fbpx

Washington State Bets Retirement Funds on Fracked Gas and Petrochemicals

The little Columbia River town of Kalama, Washington, may soon be home to the world’s largest methanol refinery. If approved by state regulators, the facility would pipe in huge quantities of natural gas to produce the petrochemical methanol for export to China, where it would be used in plastics manufacturing. A companion project in Tacoma proved to be a lightning rod of controversy, and tensions in Kalama are now coming to a boil. Governor Inslee, formerly an ardent backer of the proposals, has acknowledged that important questions remain unanswered.

Yet the state of Washington may help bankroll this project—quietly betting state employees’ retirement funds on a huge new methanol refinery in Kalama.

WSIB’s big bet on Kalama methanol

The Washington State Investment Board (WSIB), a little-known state agency, manages public investments for the state. The agency oversees public employee pensions and retirement accounts, as well as funds for labor and industry insurance and care coverage, the state’s guaranteed college tuition program, and developmental disability programs. WSIB invests public money in a range of financial instruments, including private equity funds.

The state of Washington may help bankroll this project—quietly betting state employees’ retirement funds on a huge new methanol refinery in Kalama.
Tweet This

In December 2015, WSIB voted to invest with the private equity firm Stonepeak, dedicating $400 million of public money to Stonepeak’s “Infrastructure Fund II.” It was a sizeable bet, so much so that Washington public money constitutes more than 11 percent of the fund. Stonepeak will use the fund— essentially a $3.5 billion pot of money cobbled together from various investors, including WSIB—to finance projects that may generate revenue. And as a series of emails and public documents show, one of the projects that Stonepeak may finance is the Kalama methanol refinery—something that WSIB’s trustees actually knew when they decided to invest the state’s public money.

In fact, Stonepeak has an exclusive option to finance the estimated $1.8 billion cost of building the Kalama methanol refinery using money from Infrastructure Fund II. In return for financing, Stonepeak would acquire an ownership interest (an equity stake) in Northwest Innovation Works, the China-backed company proposing the methanol refinery. Stonepeak may decide within the next year whether to fund the construction.

Poor project review and a potential conflict of interest

Stonepeak considers Washington an important business partner. Emails between WSIB and Stonepeak staff (here, here, and here), unearthed by Columbia Riverkeeper, a water protection organization, suggest that Washington has considerable influence over Stonepeak’s investment decisions. What’s more, the investments create at least the appearance of a conflict of interest: the very state employees charged with the project’s oversight have a financial stake in its development and success because their retirement funds could be invested in the project.

It is also concerning that the state has twice declined to hold the methanol proposal to the type of rigorous review standards that are common for similar energy projects. First, the Washington Department of Ecology decided not to prepare the project’s Environmental Impact Statement, giving over review to the local Port, which itself stands to make millions from methanol export. Second, the Washington Energy Facility Site Evaluation Council, the agency charged with reviewing large-scale energy developments, opted not to examine the proposal. And in the coming months, Ecology will decide whether to give the project a certification required under Section 401 of the Clean Water Act.

A gamble for public employee’s retirement funds

Apart from potential conflicts of interest, there are growing reasons to worry that the Kalama project may be a risky investment of public money. After spiking to record highs in early 2014, methanol prices in Asia collapsed, falling by more than 50 percent over the next two years. It’s true that prices for North American natural gas, the main ingredient in methanol, have declined, which might theoretically make production more profitable. But natural gas prices in Asia have declined even more. And as the price difference between the two regions has shrunk from roughly $11 to $4 (per million BTUs of natural gas), it is no longer clear whether Northwest production can compete with methanol production planned in China. (For more on the economics of producing methanol in the Northwest for consumption in China, see two analyses by Sightline: here and here.) At the very least, falling prices mean that the Kalama project is facing much stiffer headwinds than when it was first proposed in December 2013.

More broadly, it is concerning that Washington may quietly help fund facilities that are bitterly opposed by citizens on whose behalf WSIB is investing. And the dynamic is not new. In 2014, Sightline documented that WSIB had invested billions of dollars in private equity funds focused on fossil fuel investments. Many of those investments were directly linked to energy projects in the Northwest, including plans to barge coal on the Columbia River and a Bakken oil-train loading facility.

Responsibility for WSIB’s investment decisions ultimately resides with the nine voting members of the board, including the State Treasurer. Some investments, like the Kalama methanol project, seem directly at odds with Washington’s core values of environmental protection and climate leadership. At a time when the Northwest is choosing whether to become a carbon pollution export hub of global consequence or a thin green line of climate protection, how Washington invests public money says a great deal about its priorities.

Editor’s note, 12/16/16: an earlier version of this article misstated the degree of responsibility attributable to the State Treasurer. Legislation passed in 1992 transferred responsibility from the Treasurer to the WSIB itself, of which the Treasurer is but one of nine voting board members.

Check out our infographic to learn more about Kalama's proposed methanol refinery.

Seattle’s Single-Family Neighborhoods Already Include Thousands of Duplexes

With a greater diversity of home types comes a greater diversity of residents, who can enjoy and augment the benefits of walkable, amenity-rich neighborhoods.
Tweet This

When I first moved to Seattle, my family settled in my aunt’s accessory dwelling unit in West Seattle. We lived below her home in a small basement apartment, perfect for our family of three. It gave us our own space to make noise and cook meals yet also allowed my aunt to pop downstairs and get to know her great-niece (plus it gave us an on-call babysitter!).

A friend of mine—let’s call her Charlene—lives in a duplex in Wallingford. After she became a single mom, she found a duplex in her same neighborhood that offered a more affordable rent option than the single-family home she had been living in. It also allowed her daughter to maintain her friendships and social ties, rather than forcing them to uproot entirely.

Examples like these are all around because accessory dwelling units (ADUs) and duplexes pepper the map of Cascadia’s single-family zones. Having homes in a variety of shapes and sizes makes it possible for the smaller families or singles common in today’s cities to find homes there that suit their needs and budgets.

Sightline is today unveiling a detailed map (above) that shows all the multi-family housing units located in parts of Seattle that are zoned exclusively for detached single-family houses. Together, the parcels that hold these multi-family units number almost 4,600—3 percent of all single-family lots in the city. These 4,600 lots contain almost 10,200 homes, or over 7 percent of the homes in single-family zones.

Many of these multi-family homes are among the oldest in Seattle, deeply ingrained in the fabric of the Emerald City. Seattleites pass them on their morning commutes and may not even realize what they are: duplexes and triplexes nestled between single-family homes; houses with ADUs downstairs or out back.

The presence of these dwellings in every corner of the city demonstrates that Seattle’s existing single-family neighborhoods already accommodate diversity in their housing stock. And with a greater diversity of home types comes a greater diversity of residents, who can enjoy and augment the benefits of walkable, amenity-rich neighborhoods. Like in my own family’s case, and in that of Charlene and her daughter, these multi-family dwellings make it possible for Seattleites in many stages of life to find homes that fit their needs.

Diverse housing choices in Seattle’s single-family zones are largely relics of the city’s zoning history, legacies of a time when flexible residential zoning covered much larger swaths of the city. As single-family zoning spread across Seattle, it quashed housing choices in most neighborhoods. Today, single-family zoning covers more than half of Seattle, excluding parks and rights-of-way, while only about 10 percent of Seattle’s parcel land area (the private land where private owners can build things) remains open to multi-family housing types. Most of the dwellings on this map are products of grandfathering. As new zoning codes converted the city’s residential land from multi-family to single-family, city leaders allowed the existing duplexes, triplexes, and 4-plexes to stay (granting them “nonconforming use permits”) but prohibited further construction of these housing types. The one exception to this rule are ADUs, the only type of additional dwelling unit Seattle’s zoning codes currently permit in single-family zones.

In this article I explain how to navigate and use the map. In future articles I’ll delve into the zoning history that created these units and explore how they make city amenities—such as public parks and top public elementary schools—accessible to more Seattle households.

View the full map here.

Understanding the map

The map is shaded light gray for Seattle’s single-family zones and dark gray for its low-rise residential zones. By hovering your mouse over the map, you can see the specific zoning for all gray-shaded areas, such as “Residential single-family 5000” (where lots are typically 5,000 square feet) and three grades of low-rise zones.

Low-rise zones permit townhouses, rowhouses, and similar forms of residences that fall between detached, single-family homes and the four-to-eight-story apartment buildings found in mid-rise and neighborhood-commercial zones. Mid-rise, high-rise, and mixed-use zones, which hold most of Seattle’s multi-family housing, are excluded.

Each dot or polygon on the map represents a location in Seattle’s single-family zones that holds housing for more than one household.

  • The map’s green, dark blue, and yellow dots represent duplex, triplex, quadruplex, and larger multi-unit houses (let’s call them all “‘plexes”) located in single-family zones. Because low-rise zones commonly allow such housing types as a matter of course, the map does not show them in low-rise zones. Together, ‘plexes comprise two-thirds of all multi-unit homes in Seattle’s single-family zones.
  • Light blue dots represent townhouses located in single-family zones; there are just 63 of these in total, representing fewer than 2 percent of the multi-family units standing in SF zones.
  • Finally, the orange dots represent permitted accessory dwelling units. ADUs, sometimes called in-law apartments or garden suites, are the only type of additional dwelling unit city planners currently allow property owners to build on lots in single-family zones, regardless of lot size. Though Seattle is home to nearly 1,500 ADUs, the map shows only about 70 percent of them, representing all ADUs Seattleites have constructed in the last 10 years. Addresses for ADUs built prior to 2005 are not in the public record. As shown on the map, a small number of ADUs are in low-rise zones, rather than single-family zones.

Assuming that the households living in ‘plexes and ADUs are the same size as the average household in Seattle—2.1 people—the extra housing choices provide homes for an additional 12,000 people who would not have found a home in these neighborhoods had these almost 4,600 lots been occupied by only one single-family home each.

Housing in Seattle’s single-family zones

Housing Type

Number in SF zones
Detached, single-family houses ~130,000
Duplex structures 2,275
Triplex structures 420
4-plexes and larger structures 368
Townhomes 63
ADUs

1,456

Navigating the map

The map (which you may find displays better in some browsers than others; we found it works better in Chrome than in Internet Explorer) shows different information at different levels of zoom. At closer zoom levels you can access more detailed information about each unit, while at larger zooms you can more easily compare patterns between neighborhoods and across the city.

As you zoom in, the dots representing ‘plexes change to colored polygons, outlining individual land parcels on each block. Dots representing ADUs remain dots even at close zoom as ADUs don’t cover parcels. Hovering over a colored shape shows a photo of the parcel; clicking on one opens a popup box giving more information about the unit, including a streetview photo, the unit type, the year it was built, and the square footage of living space. ADU popup boxes also show the unit description from the city’s building permit record.

Here is an example, to put it all together: my uncle has lived in the Central District for nearly 30 years. He lives in an old single-family home near 15th Avenue and Alder. On his block alone are a duplex (the green rectangle), a triplex (the blue one ), and two 4-plexes (the two yellow polygons):

15th-and-alder-screenshot-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto

15th and Alder screenshot of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

Within just a few blocks of my uncle’s home are an additional four ADUs, plus 25 duplexes, and several more tri- and 4-plexes:

15th-and-alder-screenshot-2-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto-cc

15th and Alder screenshot 2 of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

By hovering on the rectangles in the live map, you can look at the Google Maps street view of each property, and by clicking on the polygons you can look at more information about each home, including its size and year of construction.

15th-and-alder-live-map-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto-cc

15th and Alder live map of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

At wider zooms, you can see how the units are spread. Though they’re found all over the city, these extra dwellings concentrate in neighborhoods closer to the center of Seattle. Compare how closely packed they are in neighborhoods such as Wallingford and Phinney Ridge with how scarce they are farther north, in areas like Maple Leaf and Wedgewood:

ne-seattle-view-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto-cc

NE Seattle view of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

Or compare the relative density in Madrona and the Central District…

central-seattle-view-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto-cc

Central Seattle view of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

…versus the comparative paucity in West Seattle and Delridge.

west-seattle-view-of-multi-unit-housing-in-single-family-zones-map-by-openstreetmap-contributors-and-carto-cc

West Seattle view of multi-unit housing in single-family zones map by OpenStreetMap Contributors and Carto (license)

Still, in every part of Seattle, single-family neighborhoods host ‘plexes and ADUs on many blocks, relics of the past and perhaps harbingers of a future in which zoning flexibility—as called for by the Seattle’s 2015 Housing Affordability and Livability Agenda and currently proposed in Portland—gives thousands of additional families such as mine and Charlene’s chances to live in the city.

Have a look yourself. If you are a Seattleite, count ‘plexes and ADUs near your home, near friends’ homes, or in neighborhoods you might like to live in. What do you find? Share your reactions below in comments. Next time, I’ll trace the history that explains why Seattle’s most exclusive zones are nonetheless sprinkled with ‘plexes.  

Notes on methods

The data for this map come from the King County Assessor, City of Seattle building permits, and City of Seattle zoning maps.

To map the duplexes, triplexes, quadplexes, apartment buildings, and townhouses, Sightline looked at the King County Assessor’s data sets. A cartographer combined these with City of Seattle zoning maps to find which multi-family units fell within the city’s single-family zones.

Data for ADUs come from two City of Seattle building permit data sets: one covering building permits finalized within the last 5 years and the other covering permits finalized between 6 and 10 years ago. A small number of permitted ADUs fall in low-rise, rather than single-family, zones. We are unsure of the exact number of ADUs in low-rise zones as this information is not included in permit data.

To calculate the number of total homes on the 4,582 lots in single-family zones that hold multi-family dwelling units, we added up the total number of homes of each dwelling type (e.g., two homes in each duplex structure, etc.). In this calculation we assumed conservatively that all 4-plex and larger structures held only 4 dwellings; we also calculated that each lot with an ADU holds 2 homes—the main home plus the ADU.

The map has additional data layers available by clicking on the Visible Layers button near the top right corner. Included are layers that show city parks as purple pentagons and the top-ranked Seattle public elementary schools as black house icons. I plan a full article on what each of these layers reveal in the future.

Thanks to map maker Jeffrey Linn of Spatialities for his tireless work to make this map as accurate as possible.

Also thank you to CartoDB for providing Sightline with a grant to use its map hosting services.

 

Weekend Reading 12/9/16: Charity Edition

We at Sightline share our favorite organizations to help inspire your end-of-year giving. We imagine these organizations will need our support more than ever in the coming years and want to amplify the great work that is happening in Cascadia and beyond. Have a favorite organization you’re giving to this year? Share it in the comments below!

Tarika

For the past month, I’ve found myself vacillating between the patriotic belief that I should spend every moment protecting the civil rights of all Americans, and the hopeless belief that I can’t do very much to shield people from the horrors of hate. Luckily there are organizations whose sole mission is to protect the civil rights of all Americans, and I can contribute to the surge in donations those organizations have received over the past month. Organizations like Lambda Legal, the NAACP Legal Defense Fund, and Southern Poverty Law Center have been working for many years to protect people of color, LGBTQ individuals and women, not to mention those of us who fall into more than one of those categories. It’s more important to me than ever to support these organizations, which will focus and help lead the tremendous work ahead.

Serena

The White Helmets, a.k.a. the Syrian Civil Defense, do some of the most dangerous work rescuing their fellow Syrians from recently bombed areas. This PBS Newshour video gives an excellent, if heartbreaking, overview of their work.

Showing Up for Racial Justice is the umbrella organization for a bunch of local chapters of white folks working to dismantle racism among fellow white folks. It asks that anyone donating also make a matching donation to a Black-led organization.

Thoughtful local media outlets are more important than ever. Seattle Globalist is doing awesome, community-led journalism centering the voices of diverse local writers and change-makers. UPDATE: The Seattle Globalist will lose nearly half of its funding in the new year. Learn why and find out more about the powerful Globalist community in this Evergrey newsletter update.

Alan

To me, among the most egregious failings of the United States is its mental health “system.” That system, too often, consists of a rotation between homelessness and jail. Ten times as many people with schizophrenia and other forms of severe mental illness are locked in American prison as are in the nation’s psychiatric hospitals and other residential recovery facilities. My favorite organization working for mental health reform is the Treatment Advocacy Center (TAC), which aims to eliminate barriers to the timely and effective treatment of severe mental illness. This month, it won a giant victory with Congress’s passage of the most comprehensive reform law on mental illness in many years.

In 1986, right after college, I spent three months in Nicaragua in the midst of the US-funded contra war. While there, I lived with a family that included a 16-year-old boy named Bladimir. For much of 2016, my daughter was in Nicaragua for a year of study abroad. I visited her, and we paid a call on Bladimir and his family. Bladimir, I learned, had been blinded at 23 while removing land mines along the country’s northern border. He has since dedicated himself to the non-profit Nicaraguan Association of the Blind and is now its president. The group helps Nicaraguan children and adults who lack sight to live happy and productive lives. One of the association’s fundraising strategies is especially near to my heart. It has formed a partnership with a nonprofit in Montreal called CycloNordSur, which has the mission of “recycling bikes up north, transforming lives down south.”

This Canadian charity collects thousands of donated bicycles, all used but working, and loads them into cargo containers. These containers fan out across the world, to grassroots groups that reassemble and sell the bikes for thrift-store prices, boosting local mobility in impoverished communities and advancing carbon-free transportation at the same time. Bladimir’s association is among these bike reassemblers. It has equipped its own bike shop and trained young mechanics. Over the years, it’s gone through several cargo-containers of used two-wheelers, and the proceeds have all paid for programs for the blind. This fall, my family, friends, and I contributed enough to send Bladimir his next cargo container of used bikes. (I have looked for but not found a similar group in Cascadia. If you know of one, please let me know! A similar US charity is Bikes for the World in Arlington, Virginia.)

Kelsey

We’re post-election 2016 and it has never been more clear to me that independent media—one that actively challenges and refuses to normalize bigotry—is more important than ever, which is why I am increasing my giving to Bitch Media. Founded and based in the Cascadian city of Portland, OR, Bitch is “a feminist media organization dedicated to providing and encouraging an engaged, thoughtful feminist response to mainstream media and popular culture.” Bitch produces a quarterly magazine, online articles, a curated daily news service, and weekly podcasts. It has been creating an inclusive, no-bullsh*t space for discourse for over 20 years.

Puget Sound Goat Rescue is an organization that has my heartstrings wrapped around its little goat hooves. This volunteer-run nonprofit rescues goats from all across the state of Washington from abusive homes, slaughterhouses, abandonment, and more. The foster goats will be taken care of until they find a loving forever home. Click here for some baby goat cuteness!

Anna

Seattle is the 23rd largest city in the US but has the fourth largest homeless population. This is a bad problem year-round. But in the dark, bitter cold months, I fear more than ever for those in our community without shelter. I donate money as well as clothes and baby supplies to Mary’s Place. I also like engaging my own kids in gift drives for kids without the means or stability for the kind of holiday every kid should enjoy. In Seattle, check out Treehouse, serving children in foster care, and links to volunteer and gift opportunities via United Way, and lists of a whole bunch more in counties across Washington.

And with “real news” getting bad and ever worse, thank goodness for outspoken comics who will help sustain us with humor and collective introspection over the holidays and the next few years. After a (IMO satisfying) rant, John Oliver implores us to do what we can to actively stand up for one another, including, for those who can afford it, financial support of organizations working on people and causes that are vulnerable during a Trump administration. In a surprising move for late night comedy television, he names specific organizations to give to (you can hear it around 19 minutes in this clip):

If you can afford the time or money, support organizations that are going to need help under a Trump administration. For instance, if you’re concerned about women’s health, donate to Planned Parenthood, or the Center for Reproductive Rights. If you don’t believe man-made global warming is a silly issue, donate to the Natural Resources Defense Council. If you don’t think refugees are a terrorist army in disguise, donate to the International Refugee Assistance Project.

Oliver goes on to remind us to both support and key an eye on the press in their role as watchdog, recommending that instead of sharing partisan memes circulating in our own echo chambers, people should support actual journalism and donate to organizations like ProPublica, “a non-profit that does great investigative journalism.” To do my part, I’ll be giving subscriptions to my loved ones instead of stuff this Christmas, to support magazines like the New Yorker who still pay professional journalists to do in-depth reporting. This is a gift that keeps on giving.

John Oliver also reminds us to check the box on the online donation pages we visit to sign up for recurring gifts. I used to give sporadically when I could or when the mood hit me, but I’m committing now to small (that’s what I can afford) monthly donations to the Southern Poverty Law Center and the ACLU.

Kristin E.

Strengthening democracy is feeling pretty important right about now, so I’m giving to the Brennan Center for Justice, FairVote, and ACLU this year. Also GiveDirectly. And our local soup kitchen: St. Francis Dining Hall.

Kristin G.

This past month has left me searching for people that seek change and embrace the idea that we need to take care of one another. We need to champion acts of love and not fall subject to more fearmongering and hate. Below are two causes I’ll be supporting this year:

My friend Jae has launched a new project called PATYL (Pay Attention to Your Life). She’s a charismatic, grab life by the horns, occupational therapist living in Ohio that schemed up a fun way to showcase people that go that extra mile. Her motto: “Healing can’t happen if we don’t pay attention. Change can’t happen if we don’t pay attention. Kindness doesn’t happen if we’re not paying attention.” I’m looking forward to watch her idea grow and see the results of the collaboration. Check out her story here.

This year I stepped away from my backyard garden beds and into a community garden. It was one of the more rewarding choices I made this year. Forging friendships in my new community, taking control of what would be on my dinner table, and encouraging curiosity amongst the neighborhood kids is just the tip of the iceberg. Consider donating to your local community garden and if you’re in need of inspiration, I give you Ron Finley.

Aven

Before I became a parent, I didn’t pay any attention to the organizations out there working on behalf of kids and families. But, as other parents, I’m sure, will be shocked to hear, raising a kid is a whole lot easier when you have the support of a knowledgeable and resourceful community to back you up. As it turns out, there are quite a few good and deserving organizations out there working to provide this kind of community, and I figured if I hadn’t heard of them, many other people probably haven’t either. So, here is a short-list of the ones my family has personally benefited from since our first kid came along almost exactly a year ago.

The Program for Early Parenting Support, or PEPS “strengthens families, increases family wellness, and prepares families to cope with life stresses by creating social, thriving neighborhood-based parent groups.” Basically this is a combination of group therapy and social hour for new parents, which, as you will know if you’ve ever been a new parent, are both welcome relief from the bewilderment and isolation of suddenly being responsible for the life and well-being of such a tiny, helpless, squalling and perpetually needy thing as a newborn baby.  Peps also offers parenting workshops and a quarterly newsletter, and all of its programs offer financial assistance for those who need it. This was especially important to my family, as my husband and I both experienced unexpectedly lengthy periods of unemployment after the birth of our son. This could have substantially increased our sense of isolation and despair during the already stressful period of learning how to care for our newborn, but thanks to PEPS we had both a reason to leave the house every week and a reliable source of support and commiseration.

Parent Trust for Washington Children “creates lasting change and hope for the future by promoting safe, healthy families and communities.” It does this through a number of programs, including offering birth and parenting classes, an emergency hotline with live parenting coaches, and free developmental screenings for children from 1 month – 5 ½ years. I can’t say enough about Marni, who does the developmental screenings. We always leave feeling both empowered by the knowledge that she shares and confident that our son is securely attached and growing well.

And finally, Pike Market Childcare and Preschool offers subsidized child care to over 2/3 of the families in their program. This is especially important in Seattle, where, as we discovered to our chagrin only after our child was born, quality childcare is egregiously expensive and difficult to find. Donations go toward supporting its Tuition Assistance program as well as a Crisis Fund that helps families who are experiencing a crisis or unexpected hardship.

Migee

The 4 year anniversary of the Sandy Hook Elementary school shooting is next week (December 14) and since then very little has been done across the nation in the way of passing common sense gun control laws. One local organization getting some traction is the Alliance for Gun Responsibility. In the most recent election, it was able to pass Initiative 1491, Extreme Risk Protection Orders:

“Extreme Risk Protection Orders allows families and law enforcement to petition a court to temporarily suspend a person’s access to firearms if there is documented evidence that an individual is threatening harm to themselves or others. The person subject to that order must surrender their guns to police and will not be able to buy, sell, or possess other firearms for up to one year.”

We need to address the violence and systemic racism toward black people and the Black Lives Matter movement has been a powerful force in bringing the issues that have existed in our communities, in our country, to the forefront of public eye. And it (as well as other organizations doing the same) needs our support. As the baton gets passed in January, I fear that groups like Black Lives Matter will need our support more than ever.

Legal Voice, formerly Northwest Women’s Law Center (a long time ago now but may be helpful to some), this small but mighty organization led by dynamo Lisa Stone has been doing critical work on behalf of women and LGBTQ folks for many years. It has focused on ending gender-based violence, ensuring access to health care, eradicating discrimination, and protecting reproductive freedom, among other things. It has a great staff, are local, and have done a lot of good for our communities.

Planned Parenthood is a 100-year-old organization “founded on the revolutionary idea that women should have the information and care they need to live strong, healthy lives and fulfill their dreams—no ceilings, no limits.” A woman’s right to make choices for her own body, have access to critical healthcare services and family planning resources will always have my support. I’ve been a Planned Parenthood supporter for many years and with what’s on the horizon, and what just happened in Ohio, it needs support more than ever.

ProPublica is an independent, non-profit newsroom that produces investigative journalism in the public interest. Our work focuses exclusively on truly important stories, stories with “moral force.” We do this by producing journalism that shines a light on exploitation of the weak by the strong and on the failures of those with power to vindicate the trust placed in them.”

I first heard about ProPublica and became a donor close to its founding in 2007 and appreciate the perspective it brings. Investigative journalism is at risk and this is an organization digging into stories and issues in a complex and meaningful way.

A new addition for me will be Southern Poverty Law Center.  When you look at its website under the What We Do section, fighting hate, teaching tolerance and seeking justice are the first three things. I’m in. In the ten days after our national election, the SPLC counted 867 incidents of hateful harassment—in just ten days. Churches are being set ablaze, mosques targeted, Nazi swastikas are finding more prominence than before, and hate has been given permission to be part of our national politics. This is not the country that I want to live in. It’s not the democracy that I know and believe in. I think the SPLC will be very busy in the coming years and will need our support. The justice system, for better or worse, cannot be dismantled in the snap of a finger so it’s possible that the law will become an even more important avenue for prosecuting hateful, unlawful, illegal acts and I want to make sure it has the support it needs.

Keiko

I’d like to highlight the work that YMCA Earth Service Corps (YESC) does to unlock the incredible power of young environmental leaders through programming in public schools around the Puget Sound region. YESC holds a huge place in my heart—it’s what motivated me to get involved in sustainability work in high school and has fueled this passion of mine ever since. Every year, YESC does a ton with very little: it organizes leadership retreats, outdoor trips, sustainability symposiums, and helps young environmental leaders find their voice and power.

Got Green’s snazzy new website alone makes me want to donate! This grassroots organization led by people of color and low income people organizes for environmental, racial, and economic justice in Seattle and beyond. Got Green constantly inspires me with its passion and programming that focuses on providing green jobs, healthy food, public transit, and healthy homes for all.

The South Seattle Emerald is another local media outlet that “acts as a powerful megaphone amplifying the voice and experience of South Seattle.” It’s written for the community, by the community, and highlights critical voices left out of mainstream news. Editor and Founder Marcus Green and other South Seattle residents can explain why you should support the Emerald better than I can in this short video.

 

Wisdom for Talking to Kids About Climate Change

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

When my daughter was four-and-a-half, she asked me point blank about climate change.

You’d think I’d be equipped for this conversation. After all, this is what I do for a living! For over a decade, I have studied the communications literature and issued dozens of talking points memos on climate challenges and solutions.

But her question left me speechless.

She had cracked open a heavily guarded vault of emotions. Everything I know and fear—and compartmentalize—about the planet’s prognosis, our broken systems, and fossil fuel politics was tied in a knot in my throat.

Think about it: dealing with climate change is about things kids already know well. It’s about cleaning up our messes; about the sun, wind, air, water, and our own bodies.
Tweet This

Nobody wants to frighten their kids. (We know even the most reasonable adults are shut down by fear.) But as the stakes grow more stark and the politics get more divisive, it’s more crucial than ever that we bring the full force of our emotions to this fight and that we raise active, community-minded, and environmentally-aware citizens. And, I believe, talking to our kids is one way to focus all our own difficult and powerful feelings in a way that fuels rather than saps our civic and political engagement.

Think about it: dealing with climate change is about things kids already know well. It’s about cleaning up our messes; about the sun, wind, air, water, and our own bodies; it’s about treating all people with respect and dignity, about stopping bullies; about sharing; and also about making rules that keep us safe—and making sure everyone follows the same rules! Young people are naturally curious, observant, and creative—they can get excited about nature, science, and new ideas.

And, most children intuitively know right from wrong. Their built-in moral compass detects and rejects injustice. And most kids aren’t yet jaded and cynical. Even teenagers are ready to question authority, fight established orthodoxy, and embrace innovations. In fact, our kids probably grasp the basics and get on board with solutions better than most grownups!

But the question remains: How do we really talk about it? How do we prepare our kids for the hard conversations and for our own emotions?

Working with ParentMap, we gathered wisdom from respected colleagues, activists, and scientists who are also parents—from Standing Rock, to British Columbia, to Portland, to Puget Sound.

  • Kandi Mossett is an organizer with Indigenous Environmental Network and a leading water protector at Standing Rock.
  • Sarah E. Myhre is a climate scientist with the Future of Ice Initiative and the School of Oceanography at the University of Washington.
  • Rev. Joseph Santos-Lyons is director of the Asian Pacific American Network of Oregon.
  • Donna Morton is a finance innovator finding ways for people to divest from harm.
  • Jana Gastellum is climate policy director for Oregon Environmental Council.
  • Kim Powe is principal at 3E Integrity and a policy expert with a focus on racial justice, equity, and sustainability.
  • Mara Gross is a communications manager at Climate Solutions in Oregon.
  • Alex C. Gagnon is a climate scientist at the University of Washington.
  • Michael Foster is an educator, mental health counselor, and activist.
  • Eric de Place is policy director at Sightline.

Here is their shared wisdom for talking about global warming and for laying the foundations for climate-conscious and community-minded children.

photo-of-kandi-mossett-used-with-permission

Kandi Mossett, by Indigenous Environmental Network (used with permission).

Kandi Mossett

I explain to my three-year-old daughter why Native Americans often talk about “Mother Earth” and make the parallels between how caretakers take care of their children and how our planet, in a very similar way, takes care of us by providing the food we need to eat, the water we need to drink, and the air we need to breathe. Once they grasp this concept, it’s easy for them to see how smoke coming out of coal-fired power plants makes the air dirty and thereby hard for us to breathe.

This past week, she picked up my little bullhorn and whispered “water is life.” It was an extremely proud moment for me.
Tweet This

I talk to children with as much encouragement as possible and let them know that anything is possible if they put their mind to it. I let them know that when they try new things, there is never a guarantee they will always succeed, but that they should at least try because if they don’t then they know for sure they will fail, and that’s no good either.

I encourage them to think from the heart about what is right and wrong. What I’ve done is a hands-on approach through experiential learning. With children of all ages, I’ve done tree plantings and community gardens, in addition to implementing recycling programs and light bulb swaps, picking up trash, and teaching about the importance of conserving energy and electricity. I do this with my own three-year-old as well.

I let them know that sometimes people in positions of power have a hard time because they’re trying to please everyone and that it may not always be possible to please everyone. I have my daughter with me at the Sacred Stone Camp and she has been absorbing everything she sees like a sponge. She’s ridden horses and played in the water. This past week, she picked up my little bullhorn and whispered “water is life.” It was an extremely proud moment for me.

Kandi Mossett is lead organizer with the Extreme Energy & Just Transition Campaign of the Indigenous Environmental Network. She has a three-year-old daughter.

 

photo-of-sarah-myhre-used-with-permission

Photo of Sarah Myhre and her son (used with permission).

Sarah E. Myhre

These are really hard questions and I am landing on these issues after a lot of growth and hard work. I’ve spent the last ten years thinking about oceans, marine ecosystems, and climate change, and I will tell you—there is so much loss and grief that I have shouldered due to the science. I have just been beside myself at times, and I think that is not an unusual response for people in our community. I mean, we are talking about changing the entire planet forever—these issues are so serious and important.

We have an immense opportunity to demonstrate the values of hope and integrity to our children, through our own actions and emotional transparency around climate change.
Tweet This

At the big picture level, I want my kid to have the emotional resiliency necessary to face problems like climate change—and to have a honed moral compass by which to see himself, our family, and our culture as part of the solution. The problem is, so much of parenting is about showing, not telling. Basically, this means that I need to demonstrate, through my own actions, what it means to be critical and self-aware of our culture of convenience and consumption. To make matters harder, I need to tend to my own emotional resiliency around this pain—I don’t have the option of numbness or apathy. Rather, I have to show up and hold a safe space open for my kid to learn about how complex, and sometimes scary, the world is.

So, this is my advice for parents: feel your feelings about this problem. Feel your feelings so that you can get to the other side, so that you can grieve and burn down the parts of you that need to go in order to rise through this and be stronger. Hold yourself to the high bar of growing up emotionally and intellectually—yeah, it hurts. Yeah, it’s not what we would prefer to be happening, but this is what it looks like to be an adult in 2016. These problems are not going to go away. They will only become more critical. We are all going to have to do this together.

In a future of climate warming, there are a lot of things at risk… things that are really scary when you contemplate the kinds of sacrifices that are down the road for us. But here’s the thing: in that future, we will still be family. We will still love each other. The things that make life worth living will still be here, and nothing can take them away. I think every parent intuitively knows that through loving one another, through loving our children and our family, we have the power to transcend and heal the world. We have an immense opportunity to demonstrate the values of hope and integrity to our children, through our own actions and emotional transparency around climate change.

Sarah Myhre is a postdoctoral scholar with the Future of Ice Initiative and the School of Oceanography at the University of Washington. She has a three-year-old son.

 

photo-of-rev-joseph-santos-lyons-used-with-permission

Photo of Rev. Joseph Santos-Lyons and family (used with permission).

Rev. Joseph Santos-Lyons

There is a saying in our religious tradition, drawn from indigenous wisdom, that asks us to consider the impacts of what we do today and how that will affect the seventh generation that will follow us. This is a lesson we teach our children.

I grew up in a middle-class family. My father worked; my mom stayed at home. I lived in the Oregon Willamette Valley and enjoyed the beautiful and abundant riches of the natural world. I took deep breaths of clean air, played in clear creeks, and played in big open spaces. Looking back after four decades, I recognize what a privilege this was, and how so many do not have the resources or rights to experience and learn from such places.

I remember being a kid, at home, in Sunday School, learning lessons of caring for the earth and all her living beings. I had the opportunity to see up close how life works together in mystical harmony, evolving, and I came to believe deeply that we are all closely interconnected. I understood my home to be more than my house, and how it encompassed my town, my valley, my state, and over time, the world.

Climate change, like everything we care about, starts in our home.
Tweet This

I loved how being outdoors made me feel so free and so grounded. I also enjoyed how it made me feel like I belonged, and thus developed a personal responsibility to care for and nurture the place I called home. Wherever I have gone, I don’t feel whole until I have developed a meaningful attachments to the place where I live. I seek to understand the history, the people, struggles, and legends that make up the fabric of a place. As a family, we create space in our storytime and at the dinner table with our children to share these stories, to inquire about what our kids see, smell, and hear. We spend time getting to know our neighbor, even when it is hard and if feels like a one-way relationship. We make and share food, crafts, cards, and quality time on our street, inviting new folks into conversation, asking about their lives, and developing trust.

It is out of this foundation that we speak of climate change with our children. We want our kids to have a finely tuned sense of the world around them, to be critical about the conditions we live in, and to carefully notice and interpret the world around them. This extends to people and the environment. We make explicit the relationship between the two, and we do our best to connect the dots so our children understand the root causes of what we see on the surface.

We discuss the foods we eat, where they come from, who grows and harvests and transports it. We are curious about the changes to weather patterns and the migration of people. Climate change, like everything we care about, starts in our home. We step back to consider our situation at a global level, and then zero in on our immediate circumstances. We ask each other, what is the impact of our actions, and who will be most affected? We strive, through all our human imperfections, to apply the lessons we have learned to live in balance with the world around us.

How can you center the seventh generation?

Rev. Joseph Santos-Lyons is director of APANO, the Asian Pacific American Network of Oregon. He is the father of three.

 

photo-of-donna-morton-used-with-permission

Donna Morton at Standing Rock (used with permission).

Donna Morton

I have been talking to my son about climate change most of his life, with different approaches as he got older. He always came with me to meetings and hearings and my TEDx talks. He learned first-hand what it means to be involved, discuss, speak up, and be political. That was his political education. He didn’t always want to go but now I realize that he was soaking everything in through osmosis—the substance of it and the spirit of serving people and the world. He’s nineteen now and a serious political animal.

When he was little, we didn’t drive a car. We took a bike or the bus for every doctor’s appointment and trip to the grocery store. He’d ask me why I didn’t drive like other mommies, and it meant we had conversations from early on about decisions we make that impact people and places, about pollution, and about climate change. We’d talk about the changing weather at first, and later I’d connect his school projects—learning about math and science—to big earth systems and climate change. He’d study water systems, nitrogen cycles, and we’d talk about daily decisions and the connection to the larger picture.

What strengthens us and centers us is our connection to nature. He grew up with an acute awareness of the world around him.
Tweet This

What strengthens us and centers us is our connection to nature. He grew up with an acute awareness of the world around him. Our play and leisure time was always in the woods or by a lake. We don’t go to the movies. When we hang out now, when we do something together, it’s usually going somewhere outside. This is a sanctuary. It’s restorative. In the woods is where we have important or serious conversations, we connect to each other, we slow down. You realize that nature is a beautiful place to talk and also a beautiful place not to talk. But being there connects you to yourself and to each other. We know that we can get spiritual comfort from going into nature. It’s fundamental to who we are.

And that’s partly because when he was growing up we were outside all the time. We practically lived outside. When he was eight years old we moved into a yurt and only used wood heat and a composting toilet. He didn’t always appreciate these choices we were making, but we had these conversations all the time about why we did things a certain way, what it meant, and what the trade-offs are. The decisions I’ve made have come with challenges—stress and strain and financial sacrifices—but as a parent, living and working in alignment with my purpose and my values has been a gift.

As a teenager questioning everything and questioning adults, my son and I always had a deep mutual respect. I am grateful that I had it easier than some other parents, because my son saw that I was doing what I love and that I didn’t sell out or just give lip service to my convictions. I kept his respect. And now that he is a young man, we align around our service to community and the world.

My son asked me hard questions and gave me new insights all along the way. Kids kick our butts. I have enormous faith in the millennial generation. I think that we need to look more astutely at millennials. They have integrity and high standards, and they want to do things differently than we did them. Rather than dismiss them because they are not doing what we did or doing it how we did, we need to ask ourselves why it is they are acting the way they do. They can teach us. And they want us to be elders. They are disappointed when they see us living in our privilege, ignoring climate change, not doing decolonization work.

These are the critical questions of our times. It’s time to ask ourselves: how do we become the elders they need us to become? How do we support them? How are we going to heal our relationships with them before we die?

Donna Morton is the co-founder and CEO of Change Finance—creating deep values ETFs for Wall Street that are fossil- and harm-free. She is a lifelong social entrepreneur, an Ashoka, Unreasonable, and Ogunte fellow. (Full disclosure: Donna was an early Sightline staffer! Her son is 19.)

 

jana-gastellum

Jana Gastellum with her children (used with permission).

Jana Gastellum

My first conversation about climate change happened after my daughter visited a fire station on a field trip. She became fascinated with fire. When she saw a picture of a globe with flames on it (a thank-you card to me from a school child), she immediately asked about it. We talked about how Mommy works to stop climate change, which is caused by pollution from cars and burning stuff for power plants. She could understand that we don’t want the world to get too hot because it will harm animals and how we grow food and get our water. Like most of us, kids are natural visual learners, and having an image open a conversation was a great aid.

I bike-commute with my daughters to their preschool. When my oldest started noticing that cars have letters on them (she was excited to find “H” like in her name), it opened up a natural opportunity to talk about different types of cars. I started pointing out the electric vehicles, explained they don’t have any tailpipe pollution, and how they’re better for our climate and our lungs.

My nine-month-old came with me to a bill signing for a renewable energy bill Oregon passed. After my three-year-old saw photos, she wanted to “play bill signing.” We talked about what laws are (they set the rules for how we do things), how laws are made (everyone should have a voice, but there are bad guys who sometimes stop good things from happening), and that the governor ultimately gets to sign bills. She, of course, wanted to be the governor.

Jana Gastellum is the Climate Program Director of Oregon Environmental Council. Her daughters are three and one years old.

 

photo-of-kim-powe-and-her-daughter-used-with-permission

Photo of Kim Powe and her daughter (used with permission).

Kim Powe

My daughter is only now turning five. She’s not ready for the scary, planetary disaster stuff. But we can teach our kids about how they are members of a community, about our collective responsibility to each other, our responsibility for other people, for our neighbors, for our community. It’s about raising good people. Our broader culture, the messages kids get, is mostly individualistic, capitalistic, consumerist. But when you talk to them about it and when you model the ways of doing things for your child as a conscientious citizen of the earth, you raise a conscientious earthling!

The driver for my environmental values is people; it’s about the powerless and people of color getting the short end of the stick. My daughter gets this.
Tweet This

You can’t have sustainability without justice or justice without sustainability. My daughter comes with me to meetings about climate change and racial justice. She’s listening (or dancing in the middle of the room). She comes to conversations at Daybreak Star and EPOC (Environmental Professionals of Color) meetings. We watched the presidential debate together. I talk to her about race. She sees that brown and Black people are treated differently. We have conversations about this. The driver for my environmental values is people; it’s about the powerless and people of color getting the short end of the stick. My daughter gets this.

We talk about solutions, and I try to instill the idea that people do things differently, and we need all the ideas and approaches we can get to make progress. There are different kinds of wisdom and knowledge—indigenous knowledge—that will be necessary parts of the solution.

All of this sets her up for climate change understanding, for seeing herself as part of a community, seeing herself as part of a global system.

And even little kids understand these community concepts if you talk to them about it: the difference between needs and wants, sharing, not taking more than we need, not wasting food and water. This is how we share, how we give to others, how we treat people, how we live in a community that takes care of people.

Kids relate to food and water. We have a garden and grow our own food. My daughter understands that we only take what we need, and if we have extra, we give it to other people.

I’m showing my daughter how to be a conscientious human being, how we all get to make choices, and that her choices have impacts. She is learning that you can do things that benefit many instead of benefitting just yourself. In the US, lots of people have the luxury to squander resources the way we do.

We use everyday illustrations to think about choices. We bike to school. She asks me if we can drive the car. It’s a chance to talk about the choice to bike and what happens when you drive a car—you make pollution—and what happens when you can choose not to do that.

There’s a myth that people of color don’t go hiking or camping. But we do. The way people of color interact with nature might not conform to conventional ways of being outdoors. But the connection to the world around you is as powerful. I remember walking with my daughter in a backpack, and we’d say, “let’s go walk in the trees.” She always had such a big smile on her face. Those connections, that feeling when you are outside and nature is your sanctuary, go with you your whole life. And we need to dispel the myth that nature is somewhere far away. It’s everywhere. It’s in your backyard, and kids can connect to it every day.

Kim Powe is a policy expert with a focus on sustainability and racial justice. She is principal at 3E Integrity. Her daughter is four years old (almost five).

 

photo-of-mara-gross-with-daughter-used-with-permission

Photo of Mara Gross with daughter (used with permission).

Mara Gross

My four-year-old doesn’t understand systemic issues yet, so we talk in terms of our personal actions and responsibility—things like turning off lights we’re not using so we don’t waste energy, biking to school because it’s healthy and fun and doesn’t make the air dirty, and making sure our camp fire is out to protect the forest from fires.

I’ve also started to lay the foundation for a future conversation about climate change. We have talked about our solar panels and how we get some of our energy from the sun, and after seeing an exhibit about space travel at our local science museum, we talked about the atmosphere and how the air keeps the temperature on our planet not too hot or too cold.

Last week she told me that she wants our next car to be electric. Why, I asked. Because gas cars are too stinky, she said. That made me smile.

Mara Gross is the Oregon communications manager of Climate Solutions. She has a four-year-old daughter

 

photo-of-alex-c-gagnon-and-his-daughter-used-with-permission

Alex C. Gagnon

The world is this incredibly beautiful, amazing, complex place. Sharing that beauty, that complexity, sharing that wonder fits very naturally with parenting. You can give kids a foundation that makes them feel connected, makes them critical thinkers and makes them think the world is a place of wonder. Given the host of challenges they will face in their lives, this foundation is more important to me than training them to fix one particular problem.

Alex C. Gagnon is an assistant professor of oceanography at the University of Washington.  He has a two-year-old daughter and a newborn.

 

photo-of-michael-foster-used-with-permission

Michael Foster

When people take action on climate is when we feel the most powerful and joyful and a sense of purpose, because we know in those moments we’re part of something bigger, doing something for someone beside ourselves. You feel alive and powerful when you know, “This is not my own self-preservation, it’s not just about me; it’s about all of us, about our society, our civilization, the next generation.”

Kids feel this kind of power, too. And I don’t try to hide things from the kids I talk to. I am very straightforward about what we are facing together. Even the big, scary stuff. It’s kind of like talking about the monster under the bed: Once you talk about the monster under the bed, now you’re not so scared.

And kids see clearly what’s good and what’s bad. They know you should stand for what’s right and not what is evil.
Tweet This

And kids jump to action. You tell an eleven-year-old that we are losing 10 billion trees per year, and they say, “Okay, what are we going to do about it?” They are unlike adults that way. They haven’t learned helplessness. It makes no sense to a kid to have a problem and not get busy fixing it right away. That positive energy and can-do spirit is empowering to kids and to the adults around them. Kids can fuel solutions in that way.

And kids see clearly what’s good and what’s bad. They know you should stand for what’s right and not what is evil.

Teens see right and wrong, too, but they have started to see that grownups don’t always do the right thing. You can channel teenagers’ anger—that anti-authoritarian, anti-establishment streak. Unlike lots of adults, they can see that it’s a dead end to wait for someone else to come along and change things. We can help them understand that the grownups are stuck. That systems have failed them. I apologize to them. I say that I know I’m part of the problem. They respond to that honesty.

And then I try to show them how powerful they really are. You should see what happens when a twelve-year-old testifies about climate change at a hearing or in court. After hours upon hours of more of the same, old, boring, technical testimony from experts and grownups, a kid’s voice stops everything. When kids talk, everyone in the room holds their breath. This is the voice of our conscience, of our future, our legacy. And it’s powerful. Kids can get excited when they see how their voice matters and how people will listen.   

Kids who are suing the Department of Ecology cannot wait until they graduate high school for emissions cuts to begin or it becomes physically impossible to return to any stable climate within their lifetime. That’s why they have been in court for two years to force Washington State to limit pollution now. And the judge in her rulings clearly understands that emergency. Making this case in an official, legal way makes it about real people and real lives.

But we need to be inspired and hopeful, too. I often ask children to imagine kids learning from a history book, a thousand years in the future. We imagine reading about what average people did—kids, parents, grandparents—to end the carbon era. The idea is that when we work together—personally, socially, politically—we can’t be stopped because we’re on the right side of history.

Michael Foster is a climate activist, Seattle mental health counselor, and father of 12-year-old and 14-year-old daughters. He has given a climate change slideshow to more than 10,000 local students and is involved in the children’s’ suit for generational climate justice, Foster v. Ecology.

 

eric-de-place-and-his-son-used-with-permission

Photo of Eric de Place and his son (used with permission).

Eric de Place

I have deep misgivings about talking climate change with my son. In part, I suspect this arises from some parental instinct to shelter our kids from the worst aspects of the world and in part because I personally find the topic almost too distressing. Can I contemplate with children the idea that our modern economy is destroying the sea life they peer at in microcosmic reverence in a tidepool? I cannot.

Coal trains are big and nasty-looking, so it doesn’t require a huge amount of abstract thinking to understand why dad might oppose them.
Tweet This

My work at Sightline has for years revolved largely around the Thin Green Line—Northwest communities’ extended fight against the ravages of coal and oil export schemes—and I have tended to use those disputes about physical infrastructure as a gateway for talking about climate protection. There’s something useful about this. Coal trains are big and nasty-looking, so it doesn’t require a huge amount of abstract thinking to understand why Dad might oppose them. And they fit neatly into the moral universe of a young child where good guys (like the Lummi Nation) fight bad guys (like Bob Murray—CEO of the largest coal mining company in America and relentless crusader against climate solutions).

Still and all, I worry. With no prompting from me, my son last year rallied his first grade classmates to chant “no oil trains” when one crossed their path on a field trip. Where does this come from? I know he picks up on what I do for a living, and I know he flushes with pride when his teacher sees his dad on TV, and so I assume he is imitating me after a fashion. My heart swells even as it recoils. Does he need to know that evil stalks our way of life? Does he need to know that desperately poor people put their bodies between their water and the dogs and guns of the government—his government—that acts on behalf of an oil company whose very business model aims to ruin his future?

Must he know this now?

Just so, I’m leaving it to his science teachers to instruct him in atmospheric carbon concentrations and adaptation strategies for rising seas. My hunch is that if we want our kids to do as we do—that is, to fight for a stable climate—we do better when we meet them on their own terrain—in the world of imagination, rather than in science and politics. As one author said, “Fairy tales are more than true—not because they tell us dragons exist, but because they tell us dragons can be beaten.”

Eric de Place is policy director at Sightline Institute. His son is seven.

How the Electoral College Could Make Every Vote Really Count

Most Americans think the candidate with the most votes should win the American presidency. States have the power to make that happen by simply agreeing to assign their Electoral College votes to the candidate who wins the most votes nationwide. In Cascadia, Washington has already done so and Oregon has a chance to follow suit in 2017.

The Constitution leaves it up to the states to choose how to assign their Electoral College votes, and in the 19th century, most states realized the best strategy for maximizing their voice as a state was to assign all their votes to one candidate—the state winner. The Constitution’s rules for the Electoral College don’t dictate this state-winner-take-all strategy, but once one state adopted the strategy, almost all the others followed suit. It’s a reasonable strategy for states but has terrible consequences for voters. And it doesn’t even do the things its defenders claim, such as protecting small states.

It’s a reasonable strategy for states but has terrible consequences for voters.
Tweet This

But there is a simple way for states to exercise the power the Founding Fathers gave them: join the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact, which would make every voter in every state count equally. The Electoral College stays in place—no Constitutional amendment required. But voters in every state would matter. Presidential candidates would vie to win the most votes across the country instead of scuffling over voters in a dozen swing states.

In my previous article, I explained how the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact cleverly uses state powers to fix today’s problems with the Electoral College. Below, I dive deeper into the history and consequences of the Electoral College, debunk common defenses of its current set-up, and dispel common arguments against a new Electoral College system that would implement a national popular vote.  

How today’s Electoral College disenfranchises voters across the US

The Founding Fathers intended to bestow the power to select the president on a small group of men “most likely to possess the information and discernment” necessary to choose a good president. Those wise electors would get together and deliberate, protecting the presidency from dangerous demagogues and con artists who might fool the masses but couldn’t fool the electors. That protection doesn’t sound so bad. The problem is, the Electoral College doesn’t actually work that way and never has.

In fact, the electors don’t deliberate. They vote how the state legislature tells them to, and for the past century or more, most state legislatures have told them to cast all their votes for the candidate who won the most votes in the state. The state-winner-take-all Electoral College strategy translates to “red” states and “blue” states, obfuscating voters’ political diversity within state boundaries. It lets every eligible voter cast a vote for the president, but it makes some votes count more than others, distorting presidential campaigns and effectively disenfranchising huge swaths of American voters.

Votes in swing state are worth more than votes in “safe” states

Under the current state-winner-take-all strategy, votes in swing states are worth more. Because winning 51 percent of the votes in a state yields exactly the same number of Electoral College votes as winning 71 percent of the votes in that state, campaigns ignore voters in “safe” states where the margin is greater than 5 percent—meaning they ignore the vast majority of American voters—and only campaign in the states where margins are close.

In 2016, candidates lavished 91 percent of their campaign stops on the 11 states with close margins. They made two-thirds of their campaign stops in just six states with margins under 2 percent.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Most states choose to give 100 percent of their Electoral College votes to one candidate, even when the other candidate won close to half the votes in that state. This state-winner-take-all system elevates a few hundred thousand votes in a few swing states to game-changing status. But candidates can safely ignore the tens of millions of voters in “safe” states—38 states plus DC. Millions of voters continue to turn in their ballots, even though their vote has no power to change the outcome of the presidential election.

In the 2016 presidential election, Hillary Clinton won 2.7 million more votes than Donald Trump; so far, Clinton has won 65.5 million votes (48.2 percent) to Trump’s 62.8 million (46.2 percent). But Donald Trump won the election because the state-winner-take-all Electoral College system weighted just 107,000 voters in three swing states as counting more than 100 million other voters across the rest of the country.

One analysis attempts to calculate the combined effect of unequal distribution of Electoral College votes and unequal electoral power between swing states and “safe” states. It estimates that Idaho ranks 39th, Oregon ranks 36th, and Washington 40th in terms of the power each voter wields in the presidential election. The state-winner-take-all Electoral College system is not kind to Cascadia.  

Votes in some small states are worth more than votes in large states

Wyoming voter has almost four times the power of a New York voter to elect the president. States get one electoral vote for each US senator and one for each representative. And since every state has two senators no matter its size, Wyoming has three electoral votes for its half a million residents (one for each US senator and one for its single representative). That works out to one electoral vote per 142,741 people. New York’s 20 million residents have one electoral vote for every 519,075 people.

Minority party votes within a state do nothing to elect the president

Are you a Republican in Oregon? A Democrat in Idaho? Thanks for voting, but your vote does nothing. The current red-state-blue-state Electoral College strategy means Oregon will assign 100 percent of its Electoral College votes to the Democrat no matter how many Oregonians like you turned in a ballot. Idaho will do the same for the Republican candidate.

You could vote or you could just watch Netflix. You could organize everyone in your community to vote with you. Or not. Your down-ballot choices will matter, but when it comes to electing the president, it really doesn’t matter what you and like-minded people in your state do.  

One solution? Use the Electoral College to create a national popular vote

A new Electoral College strategy would make every vote count

States can sign on to the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact, agreeing to assign all their Electoral votes to the national popular winner once signatories add up to 270 Electoral votes. Changing the Electoral College status quo strategy from “win the most swing states” to “win the most votes” would make every vote count. The principle of “one person, one vote” would govern America’s presidential election. One person voting in New York would have exactly as much power as one person voting in Wyoming. One person voting in a former “swing” state like Florida would have exactly as much power as one person voting in a former “safe” state like Oregon or Washington.

Conservatives in “blue” states and progressives in “red” states would have a voice

Watching the map light up red and blue states on election night makes one almost believe the illusion that Oregon has no Republican voters and Idaho no Democratic ones. Those voters exist, but they are silenced by the tyranny of the red-state-blue-state Electoral College system.

Pushing past the trickery of the “red” and “blue” state maps to look at county-level voting reveals a mass of Republican voters in Oregon and Democratic voters in Idaho. Those Americans patriotically voted, but officials might as well have thrown their ballots straight in the trash for all they matter to the presidential race.

With a national popular vote, on election night, we would watch a red bar and a blue bar build, vote by vote. Every single vote, no matter where it was cast, would add to that candidate’s potential victory. Republicans in Oregon and Democrats in Idaho could proudly turn in their ballots knowing they can watch their vote add to the victory bar.

Candidates would pay attention to convincible voters all over the country, not just in swing states

If every vote counted equally, a candidate would go everywhere there are convincible voters. She would travel around the country to talk with voters because every voter she wins over could push her to victory.

Donald Trump correctly pointed out that, with a national popular vote, he would have campaigned in other parts of the country besides the 12 swing states.

States might stop suppressing voters and start encouraging voter turnout

In the 19th century, states figured out they could wield the most clout in the presidential election by assigning all their electoral votes to a single candidate, so one by one they adopted the state-winner-take-all strategy. If states instead adopted a national popular vote—a national-winner-wins Electoral College strategy—the incentives would switch, and states could magnify their Electoral power by boosting the number of voters who cast ballots in the state. As a result, the rash of state voter suppression laws might reverse course. More states might start following Washington and Oregon’s lead by implementing vote-by-mail, on-line registration, early voting, automatic voter registration, and modern methods of cleaning voter rolls (not purging thousands of citizens from the voters rolls).

More people might participate in down-ticket races

States encouraging—not suppressing—voter participation, and presidential candidates paying attention to all voters might create a new buzz of voter participation across the United States. Some new voters would also pay attention to all candidates and vote down the ticket, increasing civic participation in state and local races.

The current red-state-blue-state Electoral College system does NOT do many of the things its defenders claim

It doesn’t protect small states

The current Electoral College system protects swing states, not small states. Small states have a disproportionate number of electoral votes, but this surplus doesn’t translate into election power. The only small state to receive attention during the presidential campaign is New Hampshire, because it is a swing state. The 12 small non-swing states together have 40 electoral votes—more than twice Ohio’s 18 electoral votes. However, Ohio received fully 73 of 253 post-convention campaign events in 2012 and 48 of 399 visits in 2016, while the 12 small non-swing states received zero visits in either year.

If protecting the interests of small states means electing a president who is ideologically aligned with most small state voters, the current Electoral College strategy fails again. The small states don’t have a “small state” ideology but are evenly divided between those that usually vote Republican (Alaska, Idaho, Montana, North Dakota, South Dakota, Wyoming) and those that usually vote Democrat (Delaware, DC, Hawaii, Maine, Rhode Island, Vermont).

Finally, one could look to the small states to see whether they think the current system is in fact better for them than a “win the most votes” strategy. Voters on both sides of the aisle in small states are chomping at the bit for a national popular vote. And of the 12 non-swing small states, ten have either signed the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact (DC, Hawaii, Rhode Island, Vermont), passed a bill through one house (Delaware, Maine), or introduced a bill (Alaska, Idaho, Montana, North Dakota). Defenders may claim the Electoral College status quo is for the good of small states, but small states seem to disagree.

It doesn’t make the United States a republic

Some defenders of the status quo point out that the United States is a republic (a representative democracy), not a direct democracy. True. But status quo apologists intimate that a national popular vote for president would create a direct democracy. Not true. In a direct democracy, people vote on issues, not officials.

Citizens’ initiatives in Oregon and Washington are examples of direct democracy. A country where voters elect a president to represent them is still a representative democracy. It’s just a republic where every vote counts equally instead of a republic where some votes count more than others.

It doesn’t elect a president who represents the states

The United States is a federal system: a collection of state governments gathered into a single nation. The US Constitution allotted limited, enumerated powers to the federal government and  reserved all others to the states. It gave state legislatures the power to choose the electors who would, in turn, choose the federal president. The Constitution does not say how legislatures must choose electors. Legislatures have complete control over that decision; they could choose electors without running a statewide election at all.

Under the current state-winner-take-all strategy, a Wyoming voter has almost four times the power of a New York voter to elect the president.
Tweet This

In practice, since the early 19th century, most states have conducted elections to measure popular will in their states. They have never sent electors without strong guidance as to whom those electors should vote for. Typically, electors are chosen because of their fervent support for a particular candidate, so no one even has to tell them how to vote. Since the 1820s, the Electoral College has been simply a mechanism for conveying the will of the majority of voters within each state; it’s not a deliberative body of wise elders. Electors are not the Constitutional equivalent of superdelegates. Consequently, presidential candidates campaign for the support of people, not states or legislators or electors. And they only campaign for the support of people in swing state.

The county-by-county breakdown in the map above shows that state lines have little to do with voters’ preferences. Oregon does not exhibit cohesive statewide interests. Western Oregon votes much more like western Washington than like eastern Oregon. Eastern Oregon, for its part, votes more like Idaho than Portland. Rather than pretending that states have coherent interests that they express in casting electoral votes, a national popular vote would let voters express their interests and would make every vote count.

A national-winner-wins Electoral College system would NOT do many of the things its attackers claim

The National Popular Vote Interstate Compact would not ditch the Electoral College or subvert the Constitution

Defenders of the status quo claim that the National Popular Vote Interstate Compact would “ditch” the Electoral College. Not true. The Founding Fathers gave states the power to control the Electoral College. States tried out different systems, first splitting their electoral votes, then consolidating their votes in a state-winner-take-all strategy. It is perfectly within their Constitutional power to try a national-winner-wins system, deciding to assign their electoral votes to the popular winner.

Candidates could not win a national popular vote by campaigning only in the biggest cities

Some status quo defenders worry that a national popular vote would mean candidates only have to win the big cities. But the big cities just aren’t that big. The 50 biggest US cities—which include Arlington, Texas, population 365,000—make up just 19 percent of the US population. Campaigning in those 50 cities and ignoring the rest of the country would be a losing strategy; even if a candidate was wildly successful in the cities, winning a whopping 75 percent of the vote, she would thereby tally just 14 percent of the popular vote. If candidates could win a popular election in cities alone, then candidates would already campaign only in the big cities of the swing states. Instead, presidential campaigns in Ohio visit Youngstown as well as Columbus and in Michigan they visit Allendale as well as Detroit. If every vote counted, candidates would do the same in every state.

A national popular vote would not encourage fraud

If you were trying to steal one of two hypothetical elections, which would you target:

  1. An election that can be won or lost by 500 to 200,000 votes in one or two geographical areas governed by one or two sets of voting rules; or
  2. an election that can only be won or lost by 500,000 to 10,000,000 voters in 50 locations with 50 different sets of voting rules.

Obviously, option (1) is more vulnerable. The 2000 presidential election came down to 537 votes in Florida—a shockingly sensitive target for fraud in a country of 300 million people. In the 2016 election, the margin of victory was 11,837 votes in Michigan; 27,257 in Wisconsin; 68,236 in Pennsylvania. An aspiring fraudster would have to be more ambitious to try to change tens of thousands of votes in three states than 500 votes in one state, but not nearly as ambitious as trying to switch the 2.7 million votes needed to change the outcome of the 2016 popular vote.

But it might improve election integrity through post-election audits

The specter of a national recount could exercise a positive impact on the integrity of American elections by spurring more states to embrace best practices for conducting routine post-election audits.

A recount is a reactive response to a crisis; when the margin is close and election officials aren’t confident the system is sufficiently free of errors that might change the election result, officials recount all votes to check the final tally. Routine post-election audits are a proactive mechanism for maintaining election integrity; by routinely auditing a statistical sample of ballots, regardless of the margin of victory, officials can reveal errors or fraud and correct them. Routine audits help officials continually improve election integrity and minimize the chance of a crisis by rooting out the potential for counting errors or fraud risks before they become a crisis. With each successive audited election, integrity improves and officials are more confident that vote counts are accurate the first time, so recounts are only needed in the closest races.

A national popular vote would not lead to a national recount

Recounts become less likely as the pool of voters gets larger. Most recounts only shift a few hundred votes. In the past six presidential elections, margins have ranged from a low of 540,000 in 2000 to 8.2 million in 1996. Even the tight 2000 race would not have warranted a national recount because of the vanishingly small likelihood that more than half a million votes could have been miscounted. But the Florida margin of 537 votes triggered a state recount (although the recount was never completed because the US Supreme Court halted it). In 2016, the national margin of 2.7 million votes comes nowhere close to recount zone, though a margin of 22,177 triggered a recount in Wisconsin.

Even as a percentage of the total vote, 2000 would not have required a recount. Recounts never shift more than a fraction of a percent of the vote, and shifts are smaller in larger voting pools. From 2000 to 2015, recounts of less than one million shifted 0.039 percent of the vote while recounts of more than two million votes shifted just 0.016 percent of the vote. The national voting pool in 2000 was 105 million so a national recount would have yielded an even smaller margin shift. But even 0.016 percent would have shifted just 16,864 votes in 2000, nowhere near enough to change the election results.

Most states set recount thresholds between 0.1 percent and 0.5 percent, with smaller margins for larger populations. After reviewing recount data, California, with a voting population of 13 million, passed a new law in 2015 setting a recount threshold of 0.015 percent for statewide races. The national voting pool is now 135 million, many times larger than any state, so a safe recount threshold would be lower than California’s 0.015 percent. Let’s say 0.01 percent. Yet even a conservative national recount threshold that’s ten times that value, 0.1 percent would have come nowhere close to triggering a recount of even the tightest presidential election in recent history; the 2000 popular vote margin was a comfortable 0.52 percent. The national margins in the other five most recent presidential races range from 1.9 percent (2016) to 8.5 percent (1996), all completely safe from recounts.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

The state-by-state winner-take-all system that evolved in the early 19th century for the Electoral College’s operation creates 51 smaller voting pools, which multiplies the probability of a recount taking place in at least one. A larger national pool decreases the chances of a recount. If the desire to avoid even the possibility of a national recount spurred more states to conduct routine post-election audits and proactively weed out counting errors, as described above, the risk of recount would diminish further.  

Let’s make every vote count

The Founding Fathers gave states the power to choose the way they cast electoral votes. States could seize that power and assign electoral votes to the popular winner, making the United States a true representative democracy. Every vote would count. Every American voter would have equal power to elect the president.

Weekend Reading 12/2/16

Serena

Some dude wrote a long book about the history and origins of consumerism and was kind enough to distill it into an interesting several-page article. In my view, the long history of moral prohibitions against the accumulation of stuff has a curious contemporary manifestation, in which a certain class of consumers is encouraged to demonstrate its values through few, but purportedly conscientious purchases of ethically sourced and produced (and more expensive) items and services. In other words, the stuff that once would have branded us excessive or immoral can now be purchased precisely to demonstrate our restraint and conscience. Odd turns…

David Kroman at Crosscut made a trip east of the Cascade Curtain to talk with Trump voters, who turn out, in fact, generally not to be the “forgotten, white, working-class” on whom most major media outlets and pundits have pinned the election (h/t The Evergrey).

Speaking of Trump voters, if anyone else needs some great resources on talking with family or friends about the election, The Opportunity Agenda compiled several great resources in one handy article.

BBC shared a series of some of the finalist animal photos of 2016 for its People’s Choice Award. I am not an animal person, honestly, but yes, sometimes you just need to marvel at wildlife.

Kristin

Only one in five Americans live in rural areas, but American institutions of democracy—the Electoral College, the Senate, the House, even for a long time state houses—give rural voters disproportionate political power.

Now that “one person, one vote” is the law in state houses, maybe states and cities can promote progressive ideas like worker cooperatives and participatory budgeting.

Financial markets are eating the American economy:

The financial sector—including everything from banks, to hedge funds to mutual funds to insurance to trading houses—represents around 7% of the economy. Yet it creates only 4% of all US jobs, and takes 25% of all private sector profits. While a healthy financial system is crucial for growth, research by numerous academics as well as institutions like the Bank of International Settlements and the International Monetary Fund shows that when finance gets that big, it starts to suck the economic air out of the room – and in fact, the slower growth effect starts happening when the sector is half the size it is today in the US.

77 percent of Americans want to increase income taxes on income over $250,000. But the Trump tax plan would do the opposite, giving the biggest tax cuts to the biggest earners: a millionaire a tax cut of $317,000.

Maria Popova on CS Lewis’s poignant and timely thoughts on democracy.

Eric

I think Joel Connelly’s recent piece on the election’s disastrous results (for Democrats) in Washington deserves more attention. With all eyeballs on Trump, it’s gone largely unnoticed that state democrats got hammered in the legislature and at the local level. It does seem like the party apparatus is not working well.

No one else around here is going to write about the Seahawks, so I’ll take this moment to note that wide receiver Doug Baldwin has become an articulate and forceful spokesperson for police reform. His agility is a thing to behold on Sundays, and this makes the game all the more fun to watch. Also, I didn’t know that his dad was a cop.

JP Sears is a genius. Not only did he get me to laugh about Standing Rock, but in 6.5 minutes he manages to provide maybe the clearest summary I’ve yet encountered. I highly recommend watching his latest video.

Keiko

David Robert’s thoughtful and comprehensive look at the election is the best analysis that I’ve read. (Plus this article is packed with hyperlinks that will keep you reading informative political pieces all weekend long.) Roberts shows how you can’t attribute Trump’s win to one issue; everything mattered. He then dives into the “everything.” Roberts debunks myths about identity politics and explains how all politics is identity politics and when you turn away from identity politics, you recenter rural white voters and view the interests of other demographics as “suspect.” I also appreciated his input on how discussions of racism get derailed by the idea of “racist” as a binary, something one is or isn’t (Robin DiAngelos good/bad binary):

So racist and sexist biases are rampant in America. Racist and sexist outcomes are rampant in America. But apparently there are very few racists or sexists in America. We just perpetuate systemic racism and sexism by accident. Oops.

Roberts also highlights the media’s empathy toward rural and small-town whites and lack of empathy toward all different kinds of people (i.e., black working class families, Muslim families):

What American mainstream pundits often cannot see is that the latitude they extend white voters—“they know not what they do, they’re good people at heart, they’re just hurting”—is the essence of white privilege.

Such latitude is not offered to other groups. Black people protesting police violence are offered no forgiveness from pundits because they’re “just hurting.” The occasional violence or extremism at those protests is never waved away as an accidental byproduct of good intentions. The US media did not parse the words of Black Lives Matter, seeking the most charitable interpretation. But they’ll do a fawning profile of angry white racists if they so much as put on a suit.

Alternative Voting Systems Can Save Democracy

What is Ranked Choice Voting? Score Voting? List Voting? And how do these election structures differ from the current winner-take-all, first-past-the-post voting system?

In this presentation hosted by the League of Women Voters of Portland, Sightline senior researcher Kristin Eberhard explores the way we vote and highlights alternative voting systems in Cascadia and beyond. Examples from the recent US election include Benton County, Oregon, and the state of Maine passing Ranked Choice Voting, a voting system that eliminates the spoiler effect, makes campaigns more positive, and elects candidates who earn true majority support.

This past US election displayed the perils of plurality voting. Cascadia can lead the way and spur a national transition to voting systems that engage more people, better reflect the American electorate, and guarantee democratic results. Find out how below:

Want more? Watch Is There a Better Way to Vote? Part 2 and Part 3 where speakers discuss how alternative voting methods better represent minorities and youth, and review Oregon’s attempts at voter reform.

 

Trudeau’s Favored Pipeline Company: Law-Breaking, Pollution, Cover-Ups

Yesterday, the Trudeau administration approved a proposal by Texas-based energy company Kinder Morgan to build a large new oil pipeline through British Columbia to the shores of the Salish Sea. Having obtained support from the Canadian federal government, Kinder Morgan will now move forward with its plans, aiming to begin construction in September 2017 and by December 2019 move tar sands to the coast for export by way of the San Juan Islands and the Strait of Juan de Fuca. The project is expected to draw ferocious opposition from Northwest tribes and First Nations, as well as from environmental advocates and local communities near the pipeline route.

Kinder Morgan is less well known than many other energy companies, but the firm has a demonstrated track record that should be alarming to residents of the Northwest. In December 2014, Sightline published an in-depth report on the company, “The Facts about Kinder Morgan,” that we believe is the most comprehensive examination of the company’s pollution, law-breaking, and cover-ups. Today, we are re-releasing that report.

Kinder Morgan has been found guilty of numerous violations:

  • Kinder Morgan has been fined numerous times by the US government for stealing coal from customers’ stockpiles, lying to air pollution regulators, illegally mixing hazardous waste into gasoline, and many other crimes.
  • Kinder Morgan’s pipelines are plagued by leaks and explosions, including two large and dangerous spills in residential neighborhoods in Canada. One hedge fund analyst has accused the firm of “starving” its pipelines of maintenance spending.
  • Kinder Morgan was convicted on six felony counts after one of its pipelines in California exploded, killing five workers.
  • In Louisiana, Kinder Morgan’s terminal spills coal directly into the Mississippi River and nearby wetlands. The pollution is so heavy that satellite photos show coal-polluted water spreading from the facility in black plumes. The same site generates so much wind-blown coal dust that nearby residents won a class action lawsuit because their homes and belongings are so often covered in coal dust.
  • In South Carolina, coal dust from Kinder Morgan’s terminal contaminates the bay’s oysters, pilings, and boats. Locals have videotaped the company washing coal directly into sensitive waterways.
  • In Houston, Kinder Morgan’s terminal operators leave coal and petcoke, a highly toxic byproduct of oil refining, piled several stories high on its properties. The company’s petcoke operations are so dirty that even the firm’s promotional literature shows plumes of black dust blowing off its equipment.
  • In Virginia, Kinder Morgan’s coal export terminal is an open sore on the neighborhood, coating nearby homes in dust so frequently that the mayor has spoken out about the problem.
  • In Oregon, Kinder Morgan officials bribed a ship captain to illegally dump contaminated material at sea, and the firm’s operations have repeatedly polluted the Willamette River.

For more details and all supporting references, download the full report, “The Facts about Kinder Morgan.”

Going Postal 2016

Fifteen pounds.

Thanks to Catalog Choice, Seattle’s phone book opt-out, and vigilance against Red Plum and other advertisers, I have purged and pinched my annual junk mail tally down to 15 pounds. Last time I weighed in, in 2013, it was 26 pounds; in 2012, it was 33 pounds (half of it from the hated Red Plum); and in 2009, the pile tipped the scale at 50 pounds. Just the phone books made up 15 pounds of it.

Time to declare victory? Nope. I am starting a new pile in January, and I’m hoping the deluge will wane to single digits during 2017.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Junk mail ads are 96 percent waste

Junk mail is not among Cascadia’s top environmental priorities, but it’s something, and it ought to be among the easiest to solve.

For one thing, junk mailers themselves crave better targeted mailing lists. If they could only mail catalogs and brochures and coupons to people inclined to buy, they’d make a lot more money. US companies spend about $46 billion mailing ads every year, but typically fewer than 4 percent of recipients respond. Junk mailers, that means, throw away more than $44 billion a year. The trouble is, they do not know which recipients are inclined to buy at any given time. By purging myself from the lists of merchants I’ll never buy from, I’m doing them a favor, saving myself time, and sparing the earth some grief.

The grief to the earth does add up. Direct mail advertising makes up approximately 2 percent of US municipal solid waste: in Seattle alone, it’s 18,000 tons of paper annually, and it boosts city waste hauling costs by about $400,000 a year. The larger environmental costs are in production, not disposal, of all that paper. A lot of forests fall, oil burns, and industrial inks are synthesized to print and deliver almost 80 billion unsolicited sales pitches per year to mail boxes in the United States.

The personal aggravation accumulates too. I shouldn’t have to spend time emailing credit card hawkers or warning every retailer from whom I request home delivery not to add me to a mailing list. I should just be able to opt out, once and for all, from unsolicited advertising carried by federal agents onto my property. As I’ve been saying, Cascadian jurisdictions should enact a Do Not Mail Registry.

Sadly, that doesn’t appear likely to happen soon.

Junk mail quantities have been dropping steadily

What is happening is that junk mail is waning on its own. Many people are, like me, fed up with it. Marketers are finding other ways to reach customers. And, above all, the internet is killing it.

Below is a figure of the total number of pieces of mail of all kinds handled by the US Postal Service each year since 1950. (Unfortunately, Cascadia-specific data are unavailable, so national numbers are the best we have to understand the trends.) Advertising mail drove the explosion of USPS deliveries starting in the late 1970s. After peaking in 2006, mail volume has fallen back to 1987 levels. The volume of mail has fallen 28 percent in the last 10 years, even as population and the economy have grown. The Great Recession likely triggered the collapse of ad mail, but other forces, mostly the internet, have sustained the decline. Canadian mail is declining too. It fell by a quarter from 2008 to 2012.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Measured per person, the shift away from paper mail is even more dramatic, as the next figure shows. Per-person mail volume almost doubled from 1977 to 1988, largely because of the explosion of junk mail. It zigzagged higher for a period, then plummeted in the Great Recession. The number of pieces of mail per person in the United States has dropped by a third in the last decade, from 14 to 9 per week. It’s now at a level last seen in 1981, the year Ronald Reagan moved into the White House.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

The steepest decline, among major categories of mail, has been first-class letters with stamps. They’re down more than half in the past decade. Advertising mail has declined less, but it’s still down by a third per household over the last decade, as the next figure shows, from 18 to 12 pieces per household per week. (Note that the previous figure was per person and this one is per household.)

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

My own junk mail, by the numbers

My own junk mail has diminished much faster than the US average, dropping by two-thirds over seven years. But, of course, I’ve been stemming the tide aggressively.

In my most recent 12 months of junk mail, unlike in past years, I found no single category of egregious offense: no phone books or Red Plum. Most of the catalogs and repeat mailers I purged in the past stayed purged. But new things crept in, most of them addressed not to me but to my now-adult children (who rarely live at home). My eldest son’s alumni association sent him a dozen pleas for contributions. My daughter got five catalogs from Aerie, a subsidiary of American Eagle. (We asked American Eagle to stop sending its catalogs last go-round, which it did, but it started sending Aerie catalogs instead.) My youngest son, meanwhile, took the medal for most pieces from a single mailer: he received 17 appeals from Planned Parenthood.

Between us, we got 20 mileage plan offers, most of them pushing credit cards. United Airlines, the previous worst offender in this category, ceased and desisted, as I requested in 2013, but others (I’m looking at you, Delta) piled on, mostly targeting my children. Ten other credit card offers also rained down on them, absent mileage plan offerings. US Bank, which used to bother me but stopped when I asked, was the main hawker.

Personally, though, I did get 16 mailings from the Wall Street behemoth Chase, all of them marketing offers for credit cards or bank accounts. Eight of them were a succession of the exact same glossy brochure, dispatched every few weeks to my mail box.

Some formerly dominant categories of junk mail in my pile shrank: Broadband marketers finally listened to my pleas and spared me their relentless junk. Cell phone companies only sent six measly postcards this year. The New York Times, however, still hasn’t honored my twice-made request to stop pitching me a(nother) subscription.

The remainder was election mailers and a miscellany of one- and two-time pieces: local shoppers; coupons from carpet cleaners and eyeglass makers and health-food vendors; two mailings from a mattress company to my ex-wife, who moved out nine years ago; announcements of art openings, theater performances, and community festivals; utility promotional offers; and announcements of new businesses, such as pizza parlors.

I’ve just completed another round of pleading for respite, firing up Catalog Choice again and emailing other advertisers directly. On January 1, I’ll start a new pile, and we’ll see if 2017 is the year that the junk mail poundage stays in single digits.

But as I’ve said, it shouldn’t be this hard. A Do Not Mail Registry would let me opt out once and for all. Unfortunately, the near-term odds of enacting such a legally binding mail box filter are slim. Here’s why.

Why the US has a “Do Not Call” registry, but not a “Do Not Mail” one

The history of the US national Do Not Call Registry sketches the most likely path to a Do Not Mail Registry. It also spotlights what a hard path it is to follow.

When the 1990s began, telemarketers were placing about 18 million calls per day to US phones; by 2002, that number had more than quintupled to 104 million—about one call per household per night. The people picking up those receivers were not happy. They complained, in growing numbers, to the Federal Trade Commission (FTC). From 1998 to 2002 alone, complaints multiplied tenfold. In response, Congress established the Do Not Call Registry in 2003, creating a way for telephone owners to opt out. It was wildly popular. Americans registered more than 10 million numbers in the first four days. By the end of 2015, the registry totaled 222 million.

Unfortunately, telemarketing companies, led by the Direct Marketing Association (DMA), succeeded in slowing implementation of the Do Not Call Registry for more than a decade. The DMA argued that the registry would damage the economy and result in 2 million lost jobs (see page 4,631). Further, it claimed the industry could effectively regulate itself with its own opt-out list (the now-defunct Telephone Preference Service).

Similar to the telemarketers of the 1990s, ad mailers today send daily doses of advertising into US homes and workplaces: two pieces per day on average. Postal customers want a Do Not Mail Registry: in fact, a 2007 Zogby poll reported that 89 percent of Americans wanted one. Nevertheless, the public is not as incensed by junk mail as it was about telemarketing; for one thing, mailings do not interrupt family dinners. The FTC gets lots of junk mail complaints but not as many.

The DMA has launched a spirited defense of ad mail. It has claimed that a Do Not Mail Registry will damage the economy and has shed crocodile tears for the future of jobs for letter carriers. It has again argued for industry-led regulation through its own direct mail opt-out list DMAChoice. The DMA has even set up its own political coalition, Mail Moves America, to block Do Not Mail.

State action helped nudge forward federal action on Do Not Call. By the time Congress established the national Registry in 2003, some 19 states had already set up their own. A similar number of states have attempted to establish Do Not Mail legislation, but not one has yet succeeded. Seattle attempted to prompt a Washington State Do Not Mail list in 2010, and it created a city-wide opt-out registry for phone books. Spokane considered a similar initiative that year, but it did not pass the city council. Unfortunately, Yellow Pages successfully sued Seattle two years later, arguing the ordinance violated its First Amendment rights, an argument that had been ineffective for the DNCR.

Canada’s anti-junk mail solution: A simple red dot

The situation in northern Cascadia, British Columbia, is somewhat better.

Although Canada does not have a national Do Not Mail list, it does have—like Australia, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom—a program allowing individuals to opt out not of all junk mail but of one major category of it: unaddressed mailings. Sometimes referred to as “saturation mailings,” these ads are delivered to every resident in an area (think RedPlum).

British Columbians who want to quit receiving unaddressed advertisements can put a red dot on their mail boxes, telling their letter carrier to withhold unaddressed paper-spam. Thanks to this program, among other things, Canadians get dramatically less paper in their mail boxes than Americans do: about five pieces per person per week, on average, rather than nine.

To win a Red Dot counterpart in the US parts of Cascadia would require action from USPS headquarters in Washington, DC, and probably from Congress, which seems no more likely in the near term than winning a Do Not Mail Registry. And states, which could in principle approve Do Not Mail Registries, do not have jurisdiction to require letter carriers to mind Red Dots.

So none of these approaches seems likely to come quickly. Public anger is not intense. Junk mail is dwindling anyway. Conservative legislators tend to heed the lobbying of the Direct Marketing Association and its ad-mail propagators; progressive legislators tend to heed the lobbying of the postal unions. Both the marketers and the letter carriers prefer to keep ads flooding our mail boxes, for their own near-term self-interest. The public interest—a mile wide but an inch deep—has few advocates.

The prospects for junk mail to jump to digital

If policy stagnation seems likely, technological stagnation does not. And information technology will no doubt keep suppressing junk mail, especially if one particular thing comes to pass. A fundamental barrier to direct mail marketers leaping the barrier from physical to digital is that email addresses are private, while physical addresses are not.

At present, for example, a new local restaurant has no way to send digital messages to homes in its neighborhood: it can only send physical mail. Unfortunately, the US Congress has banned the Post Office from creating virtual mail boxes for each address, and the one private company that tried, called Zumbox, foundered and sank in the start-up phase.

Still, postal services and private companies (here, here here, here, here, here) keep trying to hybridize mail and email, in hopes of hurrying the wanted messages onward without so much unwanted paper. And as soon as someone figures out how to give every physical address a virtual counterpart, a substantial share of marketers will stop paying for expensive paper and start sending almost-free email. Once that comes to pass, which seems inevitable given the speed of technical change, opting-out will be as easy as clicking “unsubscribe.” This change would not doom all junk mail, but it would take a big bite out of it.

How soon? I wish I knew. I’ll keep watching info tech chip away at junk mail’s domain. I’ll keep wishing for a Do Not Mail Registry. I’ll keep stacking my junk mail, and, with Catalog Choice’s help, appealing to its purveyors to cut me a break. And I’ll tally my mail again after another year has passed, because 15 pounds is 15 pounds too much.

 

P.S. A post-junk mail postal service

Every time I write about junk mail, a handful of readers object that stopping junk mail will lead to unemployed letter carriers. So let me preempt the objection: the financial troubles at the USPS are largely caused by Congress, which micromanages postal rates and constrains the service’s choices. Granted even a modicum of independence, the Post Office would do just fine. Canada Post broke even year after year, more or less, on not much more than half the mail volume per customer as the USPS, despite much longer distances to travel.

USPS postal rates, furthermore, are much lower than they could be. As Devin Leonard, author of a new history of the US Postal Service, writes:

U.S. postal rates are among the lowest in the industrialized world. In 2015, according to the USPS, it cost 96¢ to mail a 1-ounce letter in Britain and $1.51 to send one in Denmark, which is about 200 miles across at its widest, roughly 3,800 miles less than the distance from Anchorage to Palm Beach. Until recently, Spain was the only nation in the developed world that charged less; now the U.S. and Spain are tied at the bottom.

Comedian Kathleen Madigan hilariously illustrates this point: you can walk into a Post Office anywhere in the United States, hand over an envelope, pay 47 cents, and say “take this to Alaska!”

The postal service employed enormous numbers of people before the junk-mail surge that started in the late 1970s. It can still employ huge numbers in its next incarnation, in a world in which much less communication travels as paper but much more shopping takes place online. What is most valuable in postal services is not their ability to deliver pound after pound of unsolicited advertising pap to each mail box each year but their massive infrastructure for delivering other things: things of greater value, whether love letters, mail-in ballots, or parcels.

The US Postal Service is particularly impressive. It handles 40 percent of all items mailed worldwide each year, and it does so remarkably well—more efficiently and quickly than most national postal services, despite the breadth and diversity of the country it serves. Its logistics, mail sorting, and information technology are, if the butt of many jokes, nonetheless unrivaled. (Did you know that it already takes a picture of every letter and package it handles?)

The USPS physically touches almost every business and home address in the United States almost every day of the week. In its earliest decades, most of what it delivered was newspapers, and it received direct public subsidies most years for almost two centuries. Today, it relies heavily on junk mail. In the future, it may become principally a super-efficient delivery service for online purchases, perhaps even for countless recyclable artifacts 3D printed locally to consumers’ specifications. Who knows? Employment levels will probably change, but postal service itself will endure. Congress’s micro-management, not the crusade to let people say “no” to junk mail, is the real threat to the US Postal Service.

 

Thanks to Margaret Morales, who provided much of the research for this article, and to Devin Porter of GoodMeasures, who designed the figures.

Notes on Methods and Sources:

We estimate that marketers produce 4,882,000 tons of junk mail paper annually in the United States. This estimate is based on the 2012 USPS Diary Study (see page 40) which states that 86 percent of advertising mail is Standard Mail and 13.8 percent is sent First Class. Using these rates, we added estimates of municipal solid waste categories by weight from the EPA’s 2013 Materials Management Report (see page 39). This report states that 4,150,000 tons of standard mail is disposed of annually, indicating that approximately 732,000 tons of advertising mail is sent First Class.

The charts in this article are based on data from this US Postal Service information page, US Census Bureau population data, and several editions of the annual USPS publication “Household Diary Study” especially those for 2014 and 2015Canada’s mail volume (9 total billion pieces in 2015 from Wikipedia’s entry on Canada Post), divided by Canada’s 2015 population from Statistics Canada (here), suggests 4.8 pieces of mail per capita per week.

 

Inclusionary Zoning: The Most Promising—or Counter-productive—of All Housing Policies

Imagine two towns, both committed to helping their low-income residents but short on funding for social services. Both decide to require retailers to sell 5 or 10 percent of their wares at steeply discounted prices to families who qualify for benefits: milk, jeans, refrigerators, whatever. But they do it two different ways.

The first town flat-out forces stores to do it, giving them nothing back in exchange. The place gets a little better for the lowest-income families who qualified for the discount, but there are other unintended, but inevitable, consequences that hurt the whole community. Retail is highly competitive, so only the most profitable shops can afford to sell a share of their products at a loss. Lots of stores go out of business, and surviving stores tend to be ones with bigger markups and higher prices: Nordstrom, not Payless; Whole Foods, not Safeway. Prices for everybody not qualified for discounts go up. Even for those who receive the discounts, there are fewer places to shop and marked-down supplies are limited. The town overall becomes less prosperous.

The second town also requires “inclusionary pricing”—the same 5 or 10 percent discounts to qualifying families—but this town also compensates stores with economic benefits of comparable value: they can build a bigger shop than otherwise allowed under local laws; add profitable new ventures, such as liquor sales; dispense with expensive parking lots that were otherwise required; and win exemptions from certain taxes. In this community, retailers come out even and stay in business. The money they lose on their inclusionary sales is balanced out by gains from new benefits. Families with lower incomes shop where everyone else does, in a range of stores. Unlike the town that does not balance out the cost of its inclusionary pricing, this second town makes sure low-income families can thrive and be part of the local social fabric without shuttering stores and pushing up prices for those who don’t get the discount—keeping the whole community thriving and intact.

These hypothetical towns may strain belief. But as illustrations, they provide an apt analogy for the potential benefits and pitfalls of inclusionary zoning. Inclusionary zoning (IZ) is the same principle applied not to shopping but to housing. It requires builders to lease or sell a share of their new homes at below-market prices to families and individuals whose low incomes qualify them for it. Some communities balance out these affordability mandates while some do not—a difference that makes all the difference.

IZ done right, IZ done wrong

IZ done right—balancing new requirements with equal benefits to homebuilders, called “offsets” by urban planners—holds immense promise, because although where you shop does not matter much to how your life unfolds, where you live certainly does. Empirical research now demonstrates that among the best things society can do for families with lower incomes and wealth, and especially for their children, is to enable them to live in “high-opportunity neighborhoods”: neighborhoods with excellent public schools, access to good jobs, high levels of public safety, and public amenities such as parks and libraries.

Without new homebuilding, IZ can effectively freeze neighborhoods in architectural amber.
Tweet This

IZ balanced with offsets is more than an affordable housing policy. It’s a policy for opening opportunity to those long denied it. It’s a bold approach to integrating neighborhoods by class; over time, it would give chances to a substantial share of people with lower incomes and wealth to live in opportunity-rich areas otherwise affordable only to people with greater means. If the offset for developers takes the form of permission to build extra apartments—extra density—IZ is also a path beyond carbon: compact, walkable, bikable, transit-rich communities may be the most effective antidote to internal-combustion-based transportation yet discovered.

Yet few policies that cities have legal authority to adopt on their own hold so much potential for doing good if they’re done right but also for doing so much ill if they’re done wrong. If IZ imposes costs that it doesn’t sufficiently offset, it will suppress homebuilding. Without new homebuilding, IZ can effectively freeze neighborhoods in architectural amber, choke off housing choices, inflate home prices, accelerate the displacement of working families, erect walls to opportunity and inclusion, and forestall both density and affordability. Done wrong, IZ is a curse.

The two main obstacles to getting IZ done right

Though the argument for IZ with benefits to balance costs that we’ve just summarized is not controversial among most housing analysts and economists, it is deeply at odds with popular perceptions. Many people active in local politics—including many neighborhood groups, social justice advocates, politicians, and ordinary voters—seem convinced that developers make so much money they can easily absorb the costs of subsidizing rent for a share of their tenants. Go to any community meeting on housing in a prosperous city in Cascadia or beyond, and you’re likely to hear statements along the lines of: “Developers make huge profits and need to pay their fair share.” “If landlords weren’t gouging tenants, we wouldn’t have to force them.” “We need affordable housing, and they’re just going to have to pony up.”

No, real estate developers don’t win many popularity contests, and sticking it to them holds great appeal for many. The truth is, though, imposing IZ not balanced with offsets sticks it to the community, not developers. IZ without offsets will cause developers to build fewer homes—but only temporarily. When the paucity of construction yields a worsening shortage of housing, the heightened competition for homes pushes rents up that much faster. Once housing prices rise enough to make up for the expense of the new IZ rules, developers resume construction. But now every home-seeker in town has to pay more for her home, not just during the slowdown in building but ever after.

Other IZ advocates make a more nuanced argument. They do not criticize developers or landlords, do not assume outsized profits, and do not aim to punish them for their purported greed. Rather, they argue that homebuilders can cover the full costs of IZ by paying less for development sites. This argument has just enough truth in it to require examination. But in the end, it—just like the developers-are-rich-so-make-them-do-it argument—collapses under scrutiny. In this article, we take these arguments apart, piece by piece, but first, we fill in some details about how IZ works.

IZ: How and where it works across North America

IZ leverages private dollars, rather than scarce public ones

Inclusionary zoning is an increasingly popular response to the housing affordability squeeze in prospering North American cities. As sources of funding for housing subsidies in the United States have been drying up, IZ has gained favor because it provides subsidized housing without tapping strapped municipal budgets.

Nearly 500 municipalities across the continent have adopted IZ rules of one kind or another; California and New Jersey account for almost two-thirds of the programs. In Washington State, the Seattle-area cities of Redmond, Kirkland, and Kenmore have adopted IZ, and Seattle is currently developing a new IZ policy. Last spring, Oregon repealed a 17-year-old ban on IZ, and in response, Portland has already proposed an IZ program. About a third of the cities in the Metro Vancouver, BC, region have IZ in place, including Vancouver proper since 1988. This month Los Angeles became the latest major US city to join the IZ club.

IZ takes many forms

The requirements of IZ programs vary. In Boston, for example, 13 percent of the units in new buildings must be offered at rent affordable to a household earning 70 percent of the area median income ($62,000 for a household of three). New York City requires 20 percent affordable units for 80 percent of area median income ($78,000 for a household of three). Some cities allow developers to pay a comparable fee in lieu of providing subsidized units in their buildings; that money funds affordable housing projects elsewhere.

To compensate for the cost of the affordability mandates—whether that’s subsidized units or an in-lieu fee—good IZ policies are balanced with “offsets” for homebuilders. Typical offsets include expedited permitting, fee waivers, tax abatements, modified development standards, density bonuses (typically height increases), and reduced parking requirements. Seattle’s proposed Mandatory Housing Affordability program, for example, is coupled to modest upzones that give builders the opportunity to create more valuable buildings to help them manage the cost of including subsidized homes. New York City allows a 33 percent increase in building size. In contrast, San Francisco offers nothing at all to offset the financial encumbrance of its IZ requirements.

IZ’s impacts are difficult to assess

A handful of empirical studies have attempted to assess the real-world performance of IZ programs, and not surprisingly, the results are inconclusive (here is a literature review)—not surprising because isolating the effects of IZ is a triply daunting prospect. First, IZ programs are mostly municipal (city-based), while their effects spill outward into whole housing markets, which are metropolitan (regional) in scale. Second, IZ programs tend to be modest, and their effects are difficult to discern from the background noise of other policies and changing economic conditions. Third, some IZ programs are well-designed with balanced offsets, and some are not. If the value of the offsets negates the expense of the subsidized housing, a finding of no measurable effects on the housing market is just what you would expect (for examples, see this previous discussion). Indeed, a common thread in the literature is that offsets matter:

Programs with no offsets can lead to lower overall numbers of units produced…. Programs in strong housing markets that have predictable rules, well-designed cost offsets, and flexible compliance alternatives tend to be the most effective.

IZ’s potential performance can also be gauged at the project scale using standard real estate economics. For example, the New York City Housing Development Corporation recently commissioned a study of that city’s IZ policy. The report corroborates the importance of offsets, concluding that “[IZ] requirements work best… where returns are aided by the revenue from additional units allowed by changes in zoning.” Furthermore, feasibility “requires the availability of a 421-a benefit,” a valuable city property tax exemption that also functions as an IZ offset. (For those interested in running the numbers on IZ and offsets, try one of these online calculators.)

Why developers can’t eat the costs of IZ

The rules of risk versus return

Like any financial investment, private housing development is ruled by one equation: risk versus return. Developers, like them or not, build homes when they expect their income from rents or sales to cover all the costs of building (from land acquisition to lawyers, architects, engineers, construction materials, contractors, marketing, and interest on their loans) and still provide them a surplus that justifies the risk.

And the risk is considerable. A few things going wrong—a major construction defect, a slump in the market, a lawsuit, a delay in permitting—can easily lead to losses or even bankruptcy. Regulations that impose costs on developers worsen the risk-reward ratio and ultimately result in fewer new homes built.

Regulations that impose costs on developers worsen the risk-reward ratio and ultimately result in fewer new homes built.
Tweet This

In specific instances, a developer may be willing to take on a project even after its potential profit has been pared down by un-offset IZ. But overall housing production does not behave in such a binary fashion, as if there’s a certain profit threshold at which development turns off and on like a light switch. No, the sum of real estate development decisions across a city is probabilistic. The rate of new housing constructed is proportional to the potential payoff. Reduce the incentive to build by imposing new requirements for reduced-price units, and you get less housing.

In cities such as Seattle and Portland, where a housing shortage and white-hot local economies are driving up prices fast, construction is currently booming. Still, the number of new homes is trailing the ballooning pool of home seekers. Any slowdown in construction will raise prices even faster. Housing development rendered infeasible by added regulatory costs becomes feasible again if and when climbing prices boost the proposed building’s future income high enough to make up for those added costs. Developers wait it out. The real losers in this dynamic are the people with low incomes who are priced out of the city because homebuilding was delayed.

No free lunch with investors

Can developers wriggle out of the cardinal rules of real-estate economics, so that any net expenses imposed by IZ do no harm to housing affordability? Can they just eat the cost, with no ill effects? The short answer is, almost always, no. Here’s the long answer.

In most cases, investors, not developers, establish the required return on investment for housing construction. Banks will not lend to fund construction if the potential returns are low. Investors always have the option of directing their capital to investments with better return/risk profiles. They might, for example, divert their funds to an apartment project in a neighboring municipality or move it from real-estate loans to business loans or some entirely different type of investment. The same goes for the few developers with pockets deep enough to finance their own projects: if more lucrative options present themselves, why build homes?

Two ways to meet investors’ demands

To satisfy investors and lenders, developers must find a way to maintain sufficient return on investment when faced with added costs, and there are only two ways they can do that: (1) increase the income derived from the building or (2) reduce the cost of developing it.

The first option—setting higher rents or sales prices—typically isn’t an option at all. Competition among renters or buyers (a.k.a., “the market”) establishes how much they will pay, and developers are already assuming that their projects will deliver the maximum market price. No investor would take seriously a developer proposing a project that can only pay for itself by charging above-market rents. In a slim minority of cases, it may be possible for developers to make up for added costs by modifying their apartment designs to command higher rents. If so, IZ will undermine its own intent by driving up average market rents—the city gets more “luxury” homes and fewer homes affordable to the average working family. But such cases are rare, because developers already search for the most profitable building design.

That leaves the second option, namely, cutting the cost of development. Can developers make cheaper buildings? Not by much. They have no choice but to pay market rates for labor and materials. Sure, some developers manage to squeeze more out of a dollar than others, but competition among them already creates immense pressure to maximize efficiency and cut expenses. The adoption of IZ doesn’t suddenly open a door to closets full of new cost-saving techniques.

Of course another way developers can cut costs is to accept smaller paychecks, and in the end, that’s what they all do when hit with unforeseen expenses—it’s a high-risk business. But before a development project begins, all the foreseen expenses go into a developer’s spreadsheets, and they all come down to the bottom line. Expenses imposed by IZ without balancing offsets can only cut so far into the paycheck before developers will take a pass altogether and build no new homes at all. This effect is, again, not like a light switch: on average, the smaller the potential paycheck, the less likely it is that a developer will pursue construction. Some developers will still build, but not as many, and across a whole metropolitan housing market, prices will rise.

Landowners don’t have to eat IZ’s costs either

The one remaining major outlay is for land, and developers can decide how much they are willing to offer for that. The maximum price a developer will bid for land—known as residual land value—is set by how much is left in a project’s total budget after all the other development expenses are covered. If IZ drags down the balance sheet, a developer will have less to spend on the land, and the residual land value—the maximum land price that still allows a profitable development—drops accordingly (see diagram below).

But there’s a catch: sellers do not have to accept lower prices.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Original Sightline Institute graphic, available under our free use policy.

Consider a hypothetical small commercial property owned by someone who hopes to sell out and retire but needs to accumulate a big enough nest egg before he can do so. The sooner he gets the requisite offer, the sooner he can sell. If the city enacts a new IZ program that cuts what developer can pay for land by, say, 20%—a price hit likely in the range of half a million dollars for a small apartment development site—that owner will likely hold off on selling. He will bide his time and continue collecting the commercial rent until housing prices rise enough to counteract the bite IZ took out of his property value.

This “willingness-to-sell” factor was the basis for the San Francisco Controller’s Office study of “Prop C,” a ballot initiative passed in June 2016 that raised the city’s IZ requirement. The controller assumed that if Prop C reduced the amount developers could pay for building sites enough below the norm, property owners would decline to sell. The report concluded that Prop C’s 25 percent maximum mandate—requiring a quarter of new units be reserved for households with incomes from 55 to 100 percent of the area median—was too heavy a burden: the drop in the prices bid for land would stymie sales and therefore impede the construction of new homes.

Analogous to the suppression of construction caused by added costs, however, it is misguided to assume, as the San Francisco analysis does, that willingness-to-sell turns on and off like a light switch among all land owners. On average across a city, the rate of property sales to housing developers will decline along with the dollar amount developers offer. Scaling back IZ’s affordability mandates to lessen the hit on land values—as recommended by the San Francisco Controller’s study—will relieve the suppression of housing production to some degree, but it won’t shrink that negative impact to zero.

Or do they? IZ and land economics

Peculiarities about the economics of land, some IZ advocates contend, contradict what we’ve just argued. Here’s how their reasoning goes.

Within any city, the supply of land is fixed. (“Buy land,” joked Mark Twain, “they’re not making it anymore.”) This fixed supply yields an unusual relationship between price and supply. For conventional commodities—donuts, let’s say—the higher the price people will pay, the more donuts produced, and vice versa. Supply varies with price. In contrast, economists call land an “inelastic” resource: the price buyers are willing to pay has no effect on the supply. As such, any regulation or fee that knocks down the value of raw land does not reduce the availability of land for purchase.

Because supply is inelastic, the argument continues, when developers bid less for land, landowners have no choice but to sell at the reduced price. Landowners are forced to eat those losses, and sales for housing construction proceed unimpeded. For example, the Seattle-based Urbanist  blog made this argument (here, here and here) in support of an all-fee form of un-offset IZ called a “linkage fee.”  But this reasoning is critically flawed: it erroneously assumes that a targeted fee on development works like a “land value tax” (see Appendix A-2 for background).

A land value tax is a like a property tax with one key difference: it’s assessed only on the land itself and not on the improvements, that is, not on the value of the buildings standing on the land. Because bare land is inelastic, a pure land value tax does not reduce the availability of land that can be purchased for housing development or any other use—and that’s a big part of its appeal. Under a land value tax, all landowners pay a uniform rate, and they cannot avoid it. IZ, in contrast, takes effect only when new housing is built. The property owner can avoid IZ’s mandates entirely (or its in-lieu fees) simply by not building anything at all. IZ without offsets is, in short, a disincentive to build.

Furthermore, in urbanized areas, most new housing is built on property that had been generating revenue for the previous landowner—another reason expenses imposed by IZ do not behave like a benign land value tax. If the existing revenue stream is large relative to the land value, a reduction in land value caused by IZ is more likely to tip the scales against selling the property. In other words, unlike a land value tax, IZ without balancing offsets most certainly can strangle land supply (see Appendix A-3 for more details).

Un-offset IZ especially hinders property sales for housing development in places where prices and rents only marginally justify construction of new apartments and homes in the first place. Ironically, these areas are often the ones that already suffer from lack of investment. In Seattle, for example, neighborhoods in the Rainier Valley located near light rail stations fall into this category.

In high-demand US cities, lowering land values leads to fewer new homes in the near-term and escalated rents and home prices thereafter.
Tweet This

Conversely, in many locations in any growing city, the rent revenue from housing that could be developed dwarfs the existing use’s revenue stream, in which case un-offset IZ—as long as it’s not exceptionally onerous—will carry relatively little weight in the decision to pursue development. Other places fall somewhere in between. But the inescapable truth is that un-offset IZ will decrease the likelihood that new homes get built. And each project rendered infeasible might be 200 homes not available, which through the machinations of the housing market shuts about 200 low-income households out of the city.

Lastly, while bare land may be inelastic, the construction of housing is definitely not. Higher prices spark greater production, as can be observed in any city experiencing a housing boom. For example, a study of Manhattan found that “permitting activity was strongly positively correlated with lagged [housing] price changes…, a pattern we would expect in a well-functioning, unregulated market.” In other words, when prices dropped, so did homebuilding. And if prices affect the rate of housing development, then by default, prices must also be affecting the rate of property sales for development—that is, the sales are elastic.

To sum up, the key point here is that the depression of land values isn’t a get-out-of-jail-free card for IZ. Because in high-demand US cities, lowering land values leads to fewer new homes in the near-term and escalated rents and home prices thereafter.

IZ: Avoiding the backfire and realizing the potential

In cities where the lack of new homes is sending prices soaring, policymakers must carefully assess regulations that may hold back housing construction. Inclusionary zoning is no exception, notwithstanding its intent to create subsidized affordable housing. The allure of IZ is understandable: it “makes the developers pay.” It adds no expense to public budgets. It integrates affordable units into great neighborhoods.

But the promise of IZ is matched by its perils. If IZ imposes costs on homebuilding, on net, fewer homes will be built. There is no free lunch. There is no wiggling out of the economics. IZ without balancing offsets will push some prospective housing developments from black to red ink, suppressing housing choices and driving up housing prices for everyone. Rising prices, in turn, drive displacement of cities’ families and individuals with low incomes and wealth. In this way, un-offset IZ can effectively function precisely as what its proponents aim to overcome: exclusionary zoning. In places with housing shortages and rising prices, un-offset IZ is a zero-sum game at best: it helps affordability by creating some subsidized homes, but hurts affordability overall by hampering the creation of more homes overall.

Fortunately, balancing the costs of inclusionary zoning—especially with upzones, as Seattle proposes to do—can realize IZ’s promise: more market-rate housing, more affordable housing, more integration of neighborhoods by class, more choice for families and individuals, slower housing price increases for everyone, more density, more walkability, less climate change.

That’s a future worth imagining—and fighting for.

 

Appendix

The following notes provide additional details that support the main thesis of this article. We relegated them to this appendix because we suspect only the IZ aficionados will want this level of detail.

A-1: Something even better than IZ with offsets?

Our argument for the importance of offsetting IZ’s costs—ideally with upzones—begs a question: Even if properly offset, doesn’t IZ result in fewer feasible housing projects compared to the case of those same offsets applied alone? Wouldn’t offsets without IZ be even better than IZ with offsets? For maximizing overall housing choices, the answer is: yes!

Accordingly, in a perfect world, cities could do best by enacting naked upzones and integrating subsidized housing throughout their neighborhoods using tools other than IZ. Upzoning to maximize private development minimizes the need for subsidized housing in the first place, because it helps control everyone’s housing prices. The best way to fund subsidized homes is a land value tax (more on why, below), but a regular property tax would be a good second choice. Other potential sources include property tax abatements in exchange for below-market-rate units, municipal bonds, dedication of publicly owned land, real estate excise tax, and hotel tax (ideally including Airbnb).

A drawback of IZ is that its burden falls only on those who build housing. Property owners of existing buildings reap the benefits of appreciation in fast-growing cities: they sell at higher prices or collect higher rents. Yet under an IZ program, these owners, whose property values have increased largely due to the efforts of the surrounding community as a whole, nevertheless contribute zero toward the public good of providing affordable housing. IZ lets the majority of landowners off the hook. In contrast, land value taxes, standard property taxes, and bonds are shouldered equitably by all property owners.

All that said, in the real world, where public perceptions define what is politically possible, IZ with offsets is a good compromise, especially if it yields upzones that wouldn’t have been politically acceptable otherwise. Upzones allow more housing on less land, and that’s what matters most for creating an inclusionary, sustainable city. On the other hand, imposing IZ as a means to capture land value increases caused by past upzones is counterproductive: it is effectively a downzone—it results in less housing built compared to doing nothing.

A-2: Land value taxes

We love land value taxes, a rarely used variant of property taxes that are powerful tonics for prosperity, social equity, and compact development. And that’s why it’s so important to understand why IZ is a different animal.

The idea of a land value tax was first popularized in the late 19th century by writer Henry George, who advocated “taking for public use those values that attach to land by reason of the growth and progress of society.” This rationale still resonates today as property values surge in high-demand cities such as Seattle. Why should a landowner reap unearned gains largely derived from the work of all the people who invested in the surrounding community?

Unlike IZ, land value taxes encourage landowners to maximize income from all parcels by making full use of them. It discourages land speculation, a parasitic investment strategy that involves buying and holding underused urban land, such as surface parking lots and depreciated old buildings in prime locations, then waiting for land values to surge. By taxing land values, not building values, land value taxes encourage dense development.

An IZ program, absent sufficient offsets, acts like a targeted tax that penalizes conversion of existing uses to housing. In contrast, a land value tax penalizes landowners for not developing their properties to the highest and best use—the owner pays the same tax whether it’s a trash-strewn vacant lot or a $200 million glass tower. In fast-growing cities, the highest and best use is usually high-density multifamily housing, which is precisely what’s most needed to correct for a housing shortage.

A-3: Existing uses and land elasticity

In the largely built-out, fast growing cities where IZ is most commonly found, most new housing is developed on property that had been generating income for the previous owner. Almost all land in any expensive city produces revenue—even if there’s no building on the site, it can be used for paid parking.

The important role of existing uses in the dynamics of housing construction is reflected in countless zoned capacity estimates in which municipal planners assess development probability according to the improvement-to-land-value ratio: the lower the ratio, the more likely a parcel of land will be developed. Improvements that generate robust revenue have higher value, reducing the likelihood that the property will be sold for development. Likewise if a costly regulation forces land value down, the probability of development also drops.

The income stream from existing uses can vary drastically compared to the value of the land alone. If it’s a surface parking lot in a zone that allows skyscrapers, for example, the value of the revenue from parking is a tiny fraction of the value of the land, since it has the potential to hold a very expensive building. In this scenario, added regulatory costs would likely have little impact on willingness to sell because the price offered, though reduced, would still be much higher than the value of the income stream from parking.

In contrast, if it’s a functioning retail strip mall in a zone that only allows four-story apartment buildings, the value that could be created by developing may not be much more than the value of the existing commercial rent revenue. In this scenario, added regulatory costs could be enough to push down the price developers can offer for the property to the point where keeping the income-generating strip mall becomes more financially attractive than selling it. In other words, land is clearly not inelastic in this situation: a financial encumbrance on development reduces the availability of land for the construction of new housing.

A-4: When the landowner is the developer

In some cases, a would-be-developer already owns a site when a regulation is enacted that jacks up development expenses. In this scenario, the landowner is flat out of luck because she cannot make up for lost returns by paying less for land that she already owns, and there are no other options to recoup the loss. Any extra costs imposed by IZ will decrease the likelihood of housing construction, end of story.

Furthermore, if a feasibility assessment gives the thumbs-down to development for the owner/would-be-developer, then the same assessment will also give the thumbs-down to an offer for the property at the residual land value. After all, the buyer and seller both do the same math to estimate how much money could be made by redeveloping the site. Added regulatory costs put the brakes on homebuilding regardless of whether a property sale is involved.

A-5: Some inconvenient contradictions

The contention that the inelasticity of land renders regulatory fees on housing construction benign leads to contradictions that further illustrate the flaws in the argument.

First, consider the hypothetical case in which a fee is high enough to reduce the residual land value to zero—that is, the fee has pushed the cost of building so high that there’s no budget left to pay anything for land. Certainly no landowner will accept an offer of zero dollars. How can one reconcile the fact that a large fee would reduce the land supply for development to zero with the contention that a smaller fee has no impact at all on land supply?

Second, if one asserts that added costs on development don’t curtail production, it follows that reduced costs won’t boost production. A developer incentive that cuts the cost of construction would only result in builders bidding more for development sites. And so according to those who believe that the economics are controlled by land inelasticity, higher prices would not increase the rate of property sales for development, yielding no gain in housing production. And worse yet, all the financial benefit of the publicly funded incentive would be pocketed by private landowners who garner higher land prices.

Where that reasoning leads is that any time a city proposes expedited permitting or a property tax exemption or any other means of incentivizing housing development, it is unknowingly giving away cash to lucky landowners. In fact, it means it’s impossible for governments to use financial tools to influence private development in any way whatsoever because any such intervention is just absorbed into land prices! That would likely come as a surprise to the thousands of municipalities that have such policies on the books.

A-6: Are the negative impacts only temporary?

Many IZ advocates who concede that added development costs can choke the availability of development sites and impede housing production argue that the effects are temporary. In short, the claim is that “over time, developers should be able to negotiate lower prices from landowners.” It’s a curious assertion. None of the arguments presented in this article become any less valid with the passing of time. What could enable such a shift in economic decision making? Some amount of subjective irrational judgement likely plays a role in evolving expectations, but that’s shaky ground on which to base the expected outcome of a far-reaching affordable housing policy. If eventually “the requirements may be absorbed as a cost of doing business in the jurisdiction,” that is only another way of saying that housing production will proceed when rents rise high enough to overcome IZ’s costs—and that’s no win for affordability, inclusion, or the struggle against displacement.

 

Thanks to Rick Jacobus and Kristin Ryan for reviewing this article, and to Margaret Morales for help with research.